Skip to main content
← Back to A Definitions

Adjusted economic gamma

What Is Adjusted Economic Gamma?

Adjusted Economic Gamma is a concept within economic discounting and valuation that refines the process of determining the present value of future costs and benefits, particularly those extending far into the future under conditions of significant uncertainty. It extends the idea of "gamma discounting" by incorporating explicit risk aversion to future productivity shocks. This adjustment is crucial for evaluating long-term projects or policies, such as those related to climate change economics, where the appropriate discount rate is itself uncertain over extended periods.

Adjusted Economic Gamma addresses the challenge of discounting by introducing a "fear factor" that accounts for how risk-averse individuals would weigh outcomes in potential future states of the world where productivity is significantly lower. This leads to a declining discount rate over time, giving more weight to distant future impacts than a constant discount rate would. It is a nuanced aspect of applied economic models in assessing intergenerational equity and long-term investment decisions.

History and Origin

The concept of economic discounting, which is fundamental to Adjusted Economic Gamma, has its roots in classical economics, recognizing that a sum of money today is generally more valuable than the same sum in the future due to factors like time preference and investment opportunities. However, applying a constant discount rate to extremely long-term events, such as those associated with climate change, has generated considerable debate among economists. Critics argue that a high constant discount rate can significantly diminish the perceived value of future damages, potentially leading to insufficient action in the present.

In response to these challenges, Martin L. Weitzman, a prominent economist, developed the concept of "gamma discounting" to account for uncertainty about future discount rates, which naturally led to a declining discount rate over time. Building upon this, Weitzman further introduced "Risk-Adjusted Gamma Discounting" in a 2009 working paper, which was later published, to explicitly incorporate risk aversion into the discounting framework2. This extension recognizes that a society's aversion to potentially catastrophic future states, characterized by low productivity, should influence the rate at which future outcomes are discounted. This framework provided a more robust method for intertemporal resource capital allocation in the face of deep future uncertainties.

Key Takeaways

  • Adjusted Economic Gamma is an economic discounting method that accounts for uncertainty in future discount rates and incorporates risk aversion to permanent productivity shocks.
  • It typically results in a lower, declining discount rate for distant future events, thereby giving them more weight in present value calculations.
  • The framework is particularly relevant for long-term policy decisions, such as those concerning environmental protection and climate change.
  • It incorporates a "fear factor" reflecting society's aversion to extreme negative future outcomes.
  • Adjusted Economic Gamma aims to provide a more ethically sound and robust approach to intergenerational welfare comparisons in economic analysis.

Formula and Calculation

Adjusted Economic Gamma is derived within an optimal growth model, typically a Ramsey optimal growth model, combined with uncertainty about future productivity. The core idea is to "risk adjust" probabilities by marginal utility theory weights. The formula for the effective declining discount rate, ( \rho(t) ), at time ( t ) is complex but generally takes the form:

ρ(t)=δ+ημ12η2σ2Covariance Term(t)\rho(t) = \delta + \eta \mu - \frac{1}{2} \eta^2 \sigma^2 - \text{Covariance Term}(t)

Where:

  • ( \delta ) is the pure rate of time preference.
  • ( \eta ) is the coefficient of relative risk aversion.
  • ( \mu ) is the expected growth rate of consumption.
  • ( \sigma^2 ) is the variance of the growth rate of consumption.
  • ( \text{Covariance Term}(t) ) represents the contribution of the correlation between consumption growth and productivity shocks, adjusted for risk aversion, which tends to decrease the effective discount rate over time, especially when productivity shocks are permanent.

The "gamma" in Adjusted Economic Gamma (and gamma discounting) essentially refers to the role of uncertainty in future economic growth and the persistence of productivity shocks in driving this declining effective discount rate. The calculation requires sophisticated quantitative modeling and statistical estimation of these parameters over long horizons.

Interpreting Adjusted Economic Gamma

Interpreting Adjusted Economic Gamma involves understanding its implications for valuing future costs and benefits. A key insight is that the effective discount rate declines over time. This means that a cost or benefit occurring 100 years from now will be discounted at a lower rate than a cost or benefit occurring 10 years from now. This declining rate contrasts with traditional discounting, which often assumes a constant rate, and has significant implications for long-term policy evaluation.

The "adjusted" part emphasizes the inclusion of a "fear factor" due to risk aversion to potential, highly adverse future states. If there's a small but non-negligible chance of a future catastrophe (e.g., severe climate damage leading to drastically reduced productivity), then risk-averse individuals would want to weigh those low-probability, high-impact scenarios more heavily. This adjustment further lowers the effective discount rate for distant outcomes, making present actions to mitigate these risks appear more valuable. Thus, a lower Adjusted Economic Gamma value implies a stronger emphasis on protecting future generations from potential large-scale negative events. It influences how policymakers might approach long-term financial stability and sustainability goals.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a government agency evaluating two long-term infrastructure projects, Project A and Project B, both with a lifespan of 100 years. Project A offers immediate benefits but also incurs significant costs in the distant future (say, Year 90) due to environmental impact. Project B has higher initial costs but provides sustained benefits and minimal distant future costs.

Using a traditional constant discount rate of 3%, the present value of the Year 90 costs for Project A might be negligible, making the project appear more favorable.

However, if the agency applies Adjusted Economic Gamma, it might find that the effective discount rate for Year 90 is much lower, perhaps 1%. This lower rate significantly increases the future value of the environmental costs when brought back to the present. For example, a $1 billion cost in Year 90:

  • Constant 3% discount rate: ( $1 \text{ billion} / (1 + 0.03)^{90} \approx $72.7 \text{ million} )
  • Declining Adjusted Economic Gamma rate (e.g., 1% for Year 90): ( $1 \text{ billion} / (1 + 0.01)^{90} \approx $407.7 \text{ million} )

In this scenario, the Adjusted Economic Gamma approach reveals the substantial true cost of Project A's distant future environmental impact, potentially shifting the preference towards Project B, which offers greater long-term sustainability. This illustrates how the adjustment leads to decisions that better account for intergenerational well-being.

Practical Applications

Adjusted Economic Gamma finds its most prominent practical applications in areas where long-term valuation and intergenerational equity are critical. A primary application is in the economic analysis of climate change policies, where the benefits of emissions reductions materialize over centuries, while some costs are more immediate. By using a declining discount rate, Adjusted Economic Gamma provides a rationale for more aggressive climate action today, as it assigns greater weight to future climate damages and mitigation benefits.

Furthermore, this concept is relevant in assessing large-scale infrastructure projects with very long lifespans, such as nuclear waste disposal facilities or long-term resource management plans. It can also inform discussions around national debt and long-term fiscal sustainability, influencing how governments evaluate the burdens and benefits passed on to future generations. Institutions like the International Monetary Fund and the Federal Reserve regularly assess frameworks for addressing long-term risks to financial stability, implicitly considering how future economic conditions might impact present decisions. The Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) also emphasizes robust model risk management for financial institutions, underscoring the need for careful consideration of model assumptions, particularly for long-term projections1.

Limitations and Criticisms

Despite its theoretical appeal in addressing long-term uncertainty and ethical concerns in discounting, Adjusted Economic Gamma faces several limitations and criticisms. One challenge lies in the difficulty of precisely estimating the underlying parameters, such as the coefficient of relative risk aversion and the long-term probabilities and magnitudes of productivity shocks. These values are inherently uncertain and can significantly influence the resulting declining discount rate. Different assumptions can lead to vastly different policy recommendations.

Another criticism revolves around the practical implementation of a declining discount rate. While theoretically sound for long-term public policy, its integration into standard financial accounting and project evaluation, which often rely on simpler, constant discount rates derived from market interest rate observations, can be challenging. There are also debates about whether such adjustments should come from ethical judgments or solely from observed market behavior, especially when considering very distant future impacts. Some critics argue that while the intent is noble, the complexity introduced may hinder widespread adoption or lead to models that are less transparent and more prone to manipulation or misinterpretation.

Adjusted Economic Gamma vs. Gamma Discounting

Adjusted Economic Gamma is an evolution of, and closely related to, the concept of Gamma Discounting. The primary distinction lies in the explicit incorporation of risk aversion to deep uncertainty about future economic growth rates, specifically regarding permanent, potentially catastrophic, productivity shocks.

  • Gamma Discounting: This approach, also pioneered by Martin L. Weitzman, posits that if there is uncertainty about the future discount rate itself (e.g., whether it will be high or low), then the appropriate effective discount rate for distant future events will naturally decline over time. It effectively takes a weighted average of possible future discount rates, giving more weight to lower rates for very long horizons because the cumulative effect of a lower rate dominates over extended periods. It primarily addresses statistical uncertainty about the future path of interest rates.

  • Adjusted Economic Gamma: This builds upon gamma discounting by layering on an additional element: the "fear factor" associated with risk aversion to worst-case scenarios, specifically those involving permanent, adverse productivity shocks. It means that society is not just uncertain about the future, but also actively averse to the possibility of severely negative outcomes. This aversion causes individuals to attach disproportionately higher weights to states of the world where consumption growth is low (and marginal utility is high), further driving down the effective discount rate for very long-term horizons compared to pure gamma discounting. In essence, Adjusted Economic Gamma accounts for both the statistical uncertainty of the discount rate and the utility-based aversion to economic catastrophes, offering a more comprehensive framework for long-term intertemporal comparisons.

FAQs

What problem does Adjusted Economic Gamma try to solve?

Adjusted Economic Gamma attempts to solve the problem of appropriately valuing costs and benefits that occur very far into the future, especially when there is significant uncertainty about future economic conditions and a societal aversion to very negative outcomes. Traditional constant discount rate approaches can undervalue distant impacts, leading to suboptimal long-term policy decisions.

Is Adjusted Economic Gamma relevant for short-term investments?

No, Adjusted Economic Gamma is primarily relevant for projects, policies, or investments with extremely long time horizons, typically spanning many decades or centuries. For short-term investments, the impact of a declining discount rate due to long-term uncertainty and risk aversion is negligible, and traditional constant rate discounting methods are generally sufficient.

How does risk aversion play a role in Adjusted Economic Gamma?

Risk aversion plays a crucial role by introducing a "fear factor." It means that society places a greater weight on potential future states where adverse events, such as severe negative productivity shocks, lead to significantly lower economic well-being. This aversion further lowers the effective discount rate for distant future outcomes, influencing present decisions to mitigate these long-term risks.

What are common applications of Adjusted Economic Gamma?

Common applications of Adjusted Economic Gamma are predominantly found in the economic analysis of environmental policies, particularly those related to climate change, and other long-term public investment decisions where the impacts extend over many generations. It helps in assessing the present value of costs and benefits spanning decades or centuries.

Does Adjusted Economic Gamma replace other financial risk management tools?

No, Adjusted Economic Gamma does not replace other financial risk management tools like options Greeks (Delta, Gamma, Vega), which are used for pricing derivatives and hedging short-to-medium term market exposures. Adjusted Economic Gamma is a macro-economic concept for long-term policy valuation and economic models, while options Greeks are micro-level tools for managing market risk in financial instruments.