Skip to main content
← Back to A Definitions

Ak model

What Is the AK Model?

The AK model is a foundational concept within economic growth theory, a subfield of macroeconomics. It is a type of endogenous growth theory that explains how sustained economic growth can occur without relying on external, or exogenous, factors like unexplained technological advancements. Unlike earlier models that predicted economies would eventually reach a steady state with zero per capita growth due to diminishing returns to capital, the AK model posits that continuous capital accumulation can lead to perpetual growth. The model achieves this by assuming a linear relationship between output and capital, where "capital" is broadly defined to include not only physical capital but also human capital and knowledge productivity.

History and Origin

The AK model emerged in the 1980s as economists sought to address perceived shortcomings in traditional economic growth models, particularly the neoclassical exogenous growth models. These earlier models struggled to explain persistent differences in wealth between countries and relied on an unexplained "exogenous" rate of [technological progress](https://diversification. diversifcation.com/term/technological-progress) to drive long-run growth23, 24.

Paul Romer, a key figure in the development of endogenous growth theory, began working on these ideas in the early 1980s while a PhD student at the University of Chicago22. Romer challenged the notion that technological change was an external force, arguing instead that it resulted from purposeful activities and economic incentives within the marketplace20, 21. His work, for which he shared the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 2018, demonstrated how economic decisions and market conditions determine the creation of new technologies, providing a framework for understanding how knowledge can drive long-term growth19. The AK model itself, with its linear production function, represents a simplified yet powerful way to illustrate the core principle of endogenous growth, where returns to a broadly defined capital do not diminish17, 18.

Key Takeaways

  • The AK model is a fundamental endogenous growth model in economics.
  • It assumes constant returns to a broadly defined concept of capital, enabling sustained economic growth.
  • The model contrasts with neoclassical models by making technological progress an internal outcome of economic activity.
  • It highlights the importance of investment in both physical and human capital for long-term prosperity.
  • The AK model suggests that government policies can permanently influence an economy's growth rate.

Formula and Calculation

The AK model derives its name from its core production function, which is expressed as:

Y=AKY = AK

Where:

  • ( Y ) represents aggregate output (or national income).
  • ( A ) is a positive constant that represents the level of technology or the efficiency of capital. It encompasses all factors that affect productivity beyond just the quantity of capital.
  • ( K ) represents the aggregate capital stock, defined broadly to include physical capital (e.g., machinery, infrastructure) and human capital (e.g., knowledge, skills, education).

In this formulation, the marginal product of capital is constant and equal to ( A ), meaning that each additional unit of capital contributes proportionally to output, preventing the diminishing returns typically seen in other models16.

The growth rate of capital stock ((\dot{K}/K)) and thus the growth rate of output ((\dot{Y}/Y)) in a closed economy with no population growth can be derived as:

K˙K=Y˙Y=sAδ\frac{\dot{K}}{K} = \frac{\dot{Y}}{Y} = sA - \delta

Where:

  • ( s ) is the saving rate (proportion of output saved and invested).
  • ( \delta ) is the depreciation rate of capital.

For sustained growth, the condition ( sA > \delta ) must hold, implying that the rate of capital accumulation from savings must exceed its depreciation15.

Interpreting the AK Model

The AK model's interpretation centers on its fundamental assertion that economic growth can be sustained indefinitely through continuous capital accumulation. The key lies in the broad definition of "capital" to include not just physical assets but also intangible elements like knowledge, education, and innovation, which are not subject to diminishing returns at the aggregate level.

The constant ( A ) in the AK model is crucial; it reflects the overall efficiency with which capital is converted into output. Policies that enhance this efficiency, such as investments in research and development or improvements in education, can permanently increase the growth rate of an economy. Unlike models where growth eventually plateaus, the AK model suggests that a higher saving rate or an increase in the efficiency of capital (represented by ( A )) leads to a permanently higher economic growth rate, emphasizing the internal drivers of prosperity.

Hypothetical Example

Consider two hypothetical countries, Alpha and Beta, both initially with an aggregate capital stock (K) of $100 million. Assume a depreciation rate ((\delta)) of 5% per year.

Scenario 1: Country Alpha
Country Alpha has an efficiency factor (A) of 0.20 and a saving rate (s) of 25%.
Initial output (Y) = ( A \times K = 0.20 \times $100 \text{ million} = $20 \text{ million} ).
Gross investment = ( s \times Y = 0.25 \times $20 \text{ million} = $5 \text{ million} ).
Depreciation = ( \delta \times K = 0.05 \times $100 \text{ million} = $5 \text{ million} ).
Net capital accumulation = Gross investment - Depreciation = $5 million - $5 million = $0.
In this case, Alpha's capital stock is not growing, and its economy is stagnant according to the AK model's growth equation.

Scenario 2: Country Beta
Country Beta implements policies to boost its efficiency factor (A) to 0.30 and maintains a saving rate (s) of 25%.
Initial output (Y) = ( A \times K = 0.30 \times $100 \text{ million} = $30 \text{ million} ).
Gross investment = ( s \times Y = 0.25 \times $30 \text{ million} = $7.5 \text{ million} ).
Depreciation = ( \delta \times K = 0.05 \times $100 \text{ million} = $5 \text{ million} ).
Net capital accumulation = Gross investment - Depreciation = $7.5 million - $5 million = $2.5 million.
The growth rate of Beta's capital stock and output would be ($2.5 \text{ million} / $100 \text{ million} = 2.5%) per year. Country Beta experiences sustained economic growth because ( sA (0.25 \times 0.30 = 0.075) > \delta (0.05) ). This example illustrates how changes in the efficiency of capital can lead to persistent growth in the AK model.

Practical Applications

The AK model, as a cornerstone of endogenous growth theory, has significant practical applications in guiding economic policy and development strategies. It shifts focus from external forces to internal factors as drivers of long-term economic growth.

Governments and international organizations, such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF), often consider principles aligned with the AK model. For instance, the IMF provides policy advice, technical assistance, and financial resources to help countries implement sound economic policies that promote sustainable growth14. This includes fostering environments conducive to investment in both physical capital and human capital.

The model suggests that policies encouraging innovation, research and development (R&D) through incentives, education, and infrastructure development can lead to sustained increases in productivity. For example, governments might offer tax breaks for companies investing in new technologies or increase funding for educational initiatives to enhance the skills and knowledge of the workforce13. Such measures are seen as directly impacting the "A" factor in the AK model, thereby fostering continuous capital accumulation and, consequently, long-term economic expansion.

Limitations and Criticisms

Despite its importance in advancing economic growth theory, the AK model faces several limitations and criticisms. A primary critique is its core assumption of constant returns to capital, which implies that the marginal product of capital does not diminish12. This directly challenges the well-established economic principle of diminishing returns to a single factor of production. Critics argue that while the concept of capital in the AK model is broadened to include human capital and knowledge, it may still be unrealistic to completely eliminate diminishing returns in practice11.

Another criticism revolves around the empirical validation of the model. Some economists find it challenging to definitively prove the model's predictions with real-world data, as the assumptions underlying the theory can be difficult to measure accurately. The simplicity of the AK model, while useful for illustrating endogenous growth, may also be a drawback in capturing the complexities of actual economic systems. For instance, some formulations of the model may not explicitly include a separate labor factor, which could be seen as a simplification that deviates from real-world economic structures10. Furthermore, while the model suggests that government policies can permanently alter growth rates, the exact magnitude and long-term effects of such interventions are subject to ongoing debate and depend on specific policy design and implementation. Research continues to explore more complex endogenous growth models that build upon the AK framework to incorporate additional factors and nuanced interactions9.

AK Model vs. Solow Model

The AK model and the Solow model are both influential frameworks in economic growth theory, but they differ fundamentally in their assumptions about the drivers of long-run growth.

The Solow model, a neoclassical growth model, posits that sustained per capita economic growth in the long run is primarily determined by exogenous technological progress. It assumes diminishing returns to capital accumulation; as more capital is added, its contribution to output eventually decreases. This leads the economy to a steady state where net investment is zero, and per capita growth ceases unless there's an external technological improvement7, 8. An increase in the saving rate in the Solow model only has a "level effect," meaning it can increase the steady-state level of output per person, but not the long-run growth rate6.

In contrast, the AK model, as an endogenous growth theory, removes the assumption of diminishing returns to capital by defining capital broadly to include elements like human capital and knowledge. Its linear production function implies constant returns to this aggregated capital, allowing for continuous, self-sustaining economic growth5. The key distinction is that in the AK model, a higher saving rate or improvements in the efficiency of capital (the 'A' factor) can permanently increase the long-run growth rate of the economy, linking internal economic decisions directly to sustained prosperity3, 4. The confusion often arises because both models deal with capital accumulation, but their differing assumptions about returns to capital lead to vastly different predictions about long-term growth dynamics.

FAQs

What is the primary difference between the AK model and traditional growth models?

The primary difference is how they treat technological progress and returns to capital. Traditional models, like the Solow model, assume technological progress is exogenous (comes from outside the model) and that capital faces diminishing returns. The AK model, an endogenous growth theory, assumes constant returns to a broadly defined capital (including knowledge and human capital) and makes technological progress internal to the economic system, allowing for sustained economic growth.

What does "A" stand for in the AK model?

In the AK model, "A" is a positive constant that represents the level of technology or the overall efficiency of capital. It captures the impact of factors like institutional quality, human capital, and innovation that enhance how effectively inputs are transformed into output2.

How does the AK model explain sustained economic growth?

The AK model explains sustained economic growth by assuming that the aggregate capital stock (which includes human capital and knowledge) does not experience diminishing returns. This means that new investment continually contributes proportionally to output, allowing for continuous capital accumulation and, consequently, ongoing growth without an external source of innovation.

Can government policy influence growth in the AK model?

Yes, in the AK model, government policies can significantly influence an economy's long-run economic growth rate1. Policies that increase the saving rate or improve the efficiency of capital (the 'A' factor), such as investments in education, infrastructure, or research and development, can lead to permanently higher growth rates.