Skip to main content
← Back to C Definitions

Collective farms

What Is Collective Farms?

Collective farms are agricultural enterprises where multiple farmers operate their land and resources as a single, joint undertaking, often under a socialist or communist system. This approach falls under the broader economic category of command economy, emphasizing centralized control over agricultural production. The aim of collective farms is typically to consolidate land, labor, and resources to promote cooperation, increase efficiency, and meet specific production quotas set by a central authority. Such farms contrast sharply with systems based on private property rights, where individuals retain ownership and make independent decisions regarding their land and output.

History and Origin

The concept of collective farms gained significant prominence in the 20th century, particularly in the Soviet Union during the late 1920s. Joseph Stalin initiated forced collectivization as a key component of the Soviet government's push for rapid industrialization and agricultural reform. The primary goal was to eliminate individual land ownership, consolidating small plots into larger, state-managed collective farms known as kolkhozy and sovkhozy38, 39. This policy aimed to boost agricultural productivity through mechanization and to diminish the economic power of wealthier peasants, often labeled as "kulaks"36, 37.

The implementation of collectivization was often met with widespread resistance from peasants, who sometimes destroyed crops and livestock rather than surrender them to the collective farms34, 35. This resistance, combined with mismanagement and a lack of incentives, contributed to severe food shortages and famines, most notably the Holodomor in Ukraine in 1932-1933, which resulted in millions of deaths29, 30, 31, 32, 33. Despite these devastating consequences, collectivization allowed the Soviet state to extract agricultural products at low prices, providing capital for industrial investment and solidifying state control over the countryside28.

Similar systems were adopted in other communist countries, including those in Eastern Europe, China, and Vietnam, as part of broader efforts to centralize control over rural economies27.

Key Takeaways

  • Collective farms are agricultural systems where land, labor, and resources are pooled and managed jointly, often under state control.
  • They emerged prominently in socialist and communist states to centralize agricultural production and often eliminate private land ownership.
  • A primary objective of collective farms was to achieve economies of scale and increase agricultural output to support industrialization.
  • The implementation of collective farms often involved coercive measures and led to significant social and economic disruptions, including famine.
  • Modern examples of collective farming are rare; many former collective farm systems have undergone decollectivization.

Interpreting the Collective Farm

Understanding collective farms involves recognizing their economic and political context. Unlike market-driven agricultural systems, where supply and demand dictate production, collective farms operated within a planned economy. The success or failure of a collective farm was often measured not by market profitability but by its ability to meet state-imposed quotas and contribute to broader national economic plans. This often led to inefficiencies and disincentives for individual farmers, as their personal efforts did not directly translate into proportional financial reward. The system prioritized collective output and state control over individual prosperity, impacting concepts like return on investment for individual labor.

Hypothetical Example

Imagine a hypothetical country, Agraria, implementing a collective farming policy. Prior to collectivization, hundreds of small landholders, each with an average of 5 acres, cultivate various crops. The government of Agraria decides to establish the "National Agrarian Collective" (NAC) to boost wheat production and feed its growing urban workforce.

Under this new system, all private land is consolidated into large collective farms. Individual farmers become members of the NAC, contributing their land, livestock, and labor. They no longer own their plots but work collectively on vast fields. The NAC provides centralized machinery, seeds, and fertilizers, aiming for greater efficiency. The government sets a strict quota for wheat production for each collective farm. After the harvest, the entire yield is delivered to the state at a fixed, low price. Any surplus beyond the quota might be distributed among members or sold, though this often depended on state directives. This shift aims to achieve what the government perceives as economies of scale in agriculture, enabling larger-scale operations and potentially higher overall output of specific commodities, even if it disincentivizes individual initiative.

Practical Applications

While traditional collective farms, as seen in the Soviet Union, are largely historical artifacts, the underlying principles of pooled resources and collective ownership can be observed in various contemporary forms, albeit often with significant differences in structure and voluntary participation.

In some developing economies, communal land tenure systems or state-sponsored agricultural initiatives may share certain characteristics with collective farming by encouraging or mandating joint resource management for specific agricultural projects. However, these rarely involve the forced appropriation of land or the strict state control over output and pricing that defined the historical collective farm model. Modern agricultural cooperatives, for instance, allow farmers to voluntarily pool resources for purchasing supplies, marketing produce, or sharing equipment, without relinquishing individual land ownership26. This allows for the benefits of collective action, such as improved access to capital markets for equipment purchases or better negotiation power in supply chains, without the coercive elements of historical collective farms. For example, some studies suggest that rural collective economic organizations can help alleviate poverty by increasing farmers' incomes through industrial integration and improved resource allocation25.

Limitations and Criticisms

Collective farms faced numerous limitations and criticisms, primarily stemming from their coercive implementation and inherent disincentives. The lack of individual ownership and direct correlation between effort and reward often led to reduced productivity and a severe lack of economic incentive among farmers23, 24. Unlike a system based on market efficiency, where individual enterprise is rewarded, the collective farm model often resulted in a decline in agricultural output and widespread food shortages21, 22.

Forced collectivization in the Soviet Union and other countries was often accompanied by brutal repression, including the persecution of dissenting peasants and widespread famine, such as the Holodomor18, 19, 20. Even when the collective farms achieved some level of modernization through mechanization and large-scale operations, these gains were often offset by systemic inefficiencies and the profound human cost. For example, some analyses of China's decollectivization in the early 1980s challenge the notion that collective agriculture was inherently untenable, suggesting that the claimed efficiency gains from dismantling collectives might have been overstated, and that resistance to decollectivization was significant in many areas16, 17. The long-term consequences often included a dislocated rural population and a legacy of mistrust between the state and agricultural communities.

Collective Farms vs. Cooperative Farming

The terms "collective farm" and "cooperative farming" are often used interchangeably, but they represent distinct organizational structures within the realm of agricultural production, particularly concerning ownership structure and control.

FeatureCollective FarmCooperative Farming
OwnershipLand and means of production are socially or state-owned.Farmers retain private ownership of their land.
ControlTypically initiated and managed by the government/state.Formed voluntarily by a group of farmers.
Resource PoolingAll resources, including land and labor, are pooled.Farmers pool resources like equipment, marketing, or inputs, but not necessarily land ownership.15
Profit SharingProfits are divided based on labor input or state quotas.Profits are shared based on contribution (e.g., land, labor, investment) or agreed-upon terms.
VoluntarinessOften implemented through coercion or state mandate.Participation is voluntary.

Collective farms, particularly in historical socialist contexts, implied a complete surrender of individual land ownership and centralized management, with production targets and distribution largely dictated by the state12, 13, 14. In contrast, cooperative farming involves farmers voluntarily associating to achieve common goals, such as economies of scale in purchasing supplies or marketing produce, while maintaining their individual land rights9, 10, 11. This distinction is crucial for understanding the economic and social implications of each system.

FAQs

What is the main difference between a collective farm and traditional private farming?

The main difference lies in ownership and control. In private farming, individuals or families own their land and make all production decisions. In a collective farm, land and resources are pooled and owned collectively, often by the state or a cooperative union, with decisions typically made by a central authority or a collective management8.

Were collective farms successful in achieving their goals?

The success of collective farms is highly debated. While they sometimes achieved increased production of certain commodities through large-scale operations and mechanization, they often suffered from inefficiencies, lack of individual incentives, and widespread resistance, leading to significant economic and human costs, including famines5, 6, 7.

Are there still collective farms today?

While the term "collective farm" in its historical, coercive sense is rare, some countries still have state-owned farms or agricultural cooperatives that share some characteristics. However, these modern systems often involve more voluntary participation and aim to provide economic benefits to members without the forced appropriation of land seen in the 20th century4.

How did collective farms impact the lives of farmers?

The impact varied but was often profound. Farmers lost their private land and traditional ways of life. While some might have gained access to modern equipment or social services, many experienced reduced autonomy, lower living standards, and severe hardship, particularly during periods of forced collectivization and associated famines2, 3.

What is "collectivization"?

Collectivization refers to the process by which individual farmland and agricultural resources are aggregated into larger collective units. This process often involved the abolition of private land ownership and the consolidation of individual farms into collective or state-owned enterprises1. It was a key policy in many socialist and communist countries during the 20th century.