What Is Common Pool Resource?
A common pool resource (CPR) is a type of good consisting of a natural or human-made resource system whose size or characteristics make it costly, though not impossible, to exclude potential beneficiaries from obtaining benefits from its use. However, the consumption of the resource units by one person subtracts from the quantity or quality available to others, creating rivalry in consumption. This concept is central to economics, particularly within the sub-fields of resource economics and environmental economics. Common pool resources present unique challenges for resource allocation due to their combination of high excludability costs and subtractibility, often leading to issues of scarcity and potential depletion if not managed effectively.
History and Origin
The concept of common pool resources gained significant academic attention with the publication of Garrett Hardin's influential 1968 essay, "The Tragedy of the Commons." Hardin argued that individuals, acting independently and rationally in their own self-interest, will deplete a shared limited resource, even when it is not in anyone's long-term interest. "Freedom in a commons brings ruin to all," he wrote, using the example of a communal pasture where each herdsman adds more cattle to maximize individual gain, ultimately leading to overgrazing and the collapse of the pasture for everyone.10
However, the prevailing view that common pool resources were inevitably doomed to depletion was challenged by the groundbreaking work of Elinor Ostrom. An American political scientist and political economist, Ostrom demonstrated through extensive empirical research that communities often find ways to manage their shared natural resources sustainably without relying solely on privatization or centralized government control.9 Her analysis of economic governance, particularly the commons, earned her the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 2009, making her the first woman to receive the award in that category.7, 8 Ostrom's research revealed that local communities frequently develop complex, self-governing institutions and rules for managing common pool resources, effectively avoiding the predicted tragedy of the commons.6
Key Takeaways
- Common pool resources are characterized by difficulty in exclusion and rivalry in consumption.
- They pose significant challenges for sustainable management due to the potential for over-exploitation.
- The "Tragedy of the Commons" theory posits that rational individual action leads to resource depletion.
- Elinor Ostrom's work demonstrated that communities often develop successful self-governing mechanisms to manage common pool resources.
- Effective management of common pool resources often involves clearly defined boundaries, collective decision-making, monitoring, and conflict-resolution mechanisms.
Interpreting the Common Pool Resource
Understanding common pool resources involves recognizing the interplay between individual incentives and collective outcomes. While the "Tragedy of the Commons" highlights the potential for overuse, a more nuanced interpretation, informed by Ostrom's work, emphasizes that users of common pool resources are not necessarily trapped in an inevitable decline. Instead, effective governance structures, often developed through collective action, can lead to sustainability.
The key to successful management lies in establishing clear rules and norms, monitoring resource use, and implementing graduated sanctions for non-compliance. Such systems allow for dynamic adjustments based on local conditions and resource availability, fostering cooperation rather than competition. This approach stands in contrast to solutions that might propose privatization, which assigns property rights to individuals, or governmental control, which centralizes decision-making.
Hypothetical Example
Consider a shared community well providing water for irrigation to several small farms in a rural area. This well represents a common pool resource: it is difficult to exclude farmers in the community from drawing water, but each gallon drawn by one farmer reduces the amount available for others, demonstrating rivalry in consumption.
If there are no rules or agreements, each farmer might draw as much water as possible to maximize their crop yield, fearing that if they don't, others will take the water. This individualistic behavior, while rational for each farmer in the short term, could lead to the water table dropping dangerously low, eventually drying up the well for everyone. This illustrates the core dilemma of a common pool resource.
However, if the farmers collectively agree on rules—for example, each farm can only draw a specific amount of water per day, or drawing is restricted to certain hours—and they establish a system to monitor water levels and adherence to the rules, the well can be sustained for years. They might even implement a system of graduated sanctions (like warnings, then fines) for those who violate the rules, ensuring compliance and long-term viability.
Practical Applications
Common pool resources are ubiquitous in the real world, influencing various sectors, from natural resource management to infrastructure. Examples include:
- Fisheries: Ocean fisheries are classic common pool resources. Without effective management, overfishing by individual vessels can deplete fish stocks, impacting all fishermen and the ecosystem.
- Forests: Community forests, where local residents harvest timber or non-timber forest products, require careful management to prevent deforestation and ensure long-term productivity.
- Irrigation Systems: Complex irrigation systems that deliver water to multiple farmers exhibit common pool characteristics, as individual water withdrawals affect availability for others downstream. Studies show that integrated approaches to large-scale common-pool water resource management, such as those implemented in Nebraska's Platte River basin, can achieve sustainable outcomes.
- 5 Groundwater Basins: Underground aquifers serving multiple users can be over-extracted, leading to depletion or saltwater intrusion, unless collective management strategies are adopted. Research on groundwater management has highlighted the importance of community-based strategies for overcoming collective action problems.
Th3, 4e successful management of these resources often involves understanding the local context, fostering trust among users, and designing institutions that align individual incentives with the collective good, moving beyond simplistic solutions of pure private goods or state control.
Limitations and Criticisms
While the concept of common pool resources and the associated strategies for their management have significantly advanced our understanding of resource governance, certain limitations and criticisms exist. One notable critique questions whether Ostrom's "commons" truly differ from partnership arrangements that could be seen as a form of private property. It is argued that Ostrom may not have sufficiently distinguished between situations where outsiders can be truly excluded and those where exclusion is merely costly. Thi2s perspective suggests that many of the successful "commons" examples might, in essence, function as forms of collectively owned private property, rather than an entirely new category of resource.
Another challenge arises from the complexity and scale of some common pool resources. While local, well-defined communities may successfully self-organize, global common pool resources like the atmosphere or the oceans face immense difficulties in achieving consensus and enforcing rules among a vast and diverse set of actors. The presence of externalities and the potential for market failure remain significant concerns, especially when global cooperation is required to address issues like climate change or ocean plastic pollution. Furthermore, power imbalances within user groups can undermine collective action, as actors with disproportionate power may have less incentive to participate in equitable management.
##1 Common Pool Resource vs. Public Good
Common pool resources are often confused with public goods, but they possess distinct economic characteristics. The primary difference lies in the concept of rivalry in consumption.
Feature | Common Pool Resource | Public Good |
---|---|---|
Excludability | Low (costly or difficult to prevent use) | Low (non-excludable) |
Rivalry | High (one person's use diminishes availability) | Low (one person's use does not diminish for others) |
Examples | Fisheries, forests, groundwater, irrigation systems | National defense, street lights, clean air |
While both common pool resources and public goods are non-excludable (or costly to exclude users), the key distinguishing factor is that consumption of a common pool resource is rivalrous, meaning that one person's use subtracts from another's. In contrast, a pure public good is non-rivalrous, so many individuals can consume it simultaneously without diminishing its availability for others. This distinction impacts how economic efficiency is achieved and what governance mechanisms are most appropriate.
FAQs
Q: What makes a resource a "common pool resource"?
A: A resource is classified as a common pool resource if it is difficult or costly to exclude people from using it, and if one person's use of the resource reduces the amount available for others. This combination of low excludability and high rivalry defines a common pool resource.
Q: Is the "Tragedy of the Commons" an inevitable outcome for all common pool resources?
A: Not necessarily. While the "Tragedy of the Commons" highlights a potential outcome, the work of Elinor Ostrom and others has demonstrated that many communities successfully manage common pool resources through self-governance, collective rules, and monitoring, thus avoiding depletion. The outcome depends heavily on the institutional arrangements and the capacity for game theory principles to align incentives.
Q: How is a common pool resource different from a private good?
A: A private good is both excludable (it's easy to prevent someone from consuming it if they don't pay) and rivalrous (one person's consumption prevents another's). Common pool resources, conversely, are rivalrous but difficult to exclude. For example, a slice of pizza is a private good, but a fishing ground in a public lake is a common pool resource.
Q: What are some common challenges in managing common pool resources?
A: Challenges include defining clear boundaries, establishing fair rules for access and use, monitoring compliance, resolving conflicts among users, and adapting rules to changing conditions. The temptation for individual users to maximize their own benefit without considering the long-term impact on the collective resource, known as the "free-rider problem," is also a significant hurdle.