Skip to main content
← Back to C Definitions

Constant elasticity of substitution production function

What Is Constant Elasticity of Substitution Production Function?

The constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function is a mathematical formulation in neoclassical economics that describes how various input factors, such as capital and labor, can be combined to produce output. This type of production function belongs to the broader category of economic models and is characterized by a consistent elasticity of substitution between its inputs, meaning the ease with which one input can be substituted for another remains constant regardless of the level of output or input usage. The CES production function is widely used in economic theory and empirical analysis to understand production processes and factor allocation. It also has a counterpart in consumer theory, known as the CES utility functions, which exhibits similar properties regarding the substitution between different goods or services.

History and Origin

The constant elasticity of substitution production function was formally introduced to the field of economics in a seminal 1961 paper titled "Capital-Labor Substitution and Economic Efficiency." This influential work was co-authored by economists Kenneth Arrow, Hollis Chenery, Bagicha Minhas, and Robert Solow.25 The paper arose from empirical observations about capital-labor ratios and wage rates across different countries and industries, which suggested that the elasticity of substitution between these factors was not necessarily unity, as implied by the widely used Cobb-Douglas function.24,23 The development of the CES production function provided a more flexible framework for modeling the relationship between inputs and output, allowing for varying degrees of substitutability.22 This innovation had a significant and immediate impact on economic research, becoming an important tool for both theoretical and empirical studies.21

Key Takeaways

  • The Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function describes how inputs can be combined to produce output, assuming a constant elasticity of substitution between inputs.
  • It is a more general form than the Cobb-Douglas production function, allowing for elasticity of substitution values other than one.
  • The CES function is crucial for analyzing factor shares, technological change, and economic growth in macroeconomics.
  • Its parameters include an efficiency parameter, distribution parameters representing factor shares, and a substitution parameter.
  • Special cases of the CES function include the Cobb-Douglas and Leontief production functions.

Formula and Calculation

For a two-input model using capital ($K$) and labor ($L$), the general form of the constant elasticity of substitution production function is:

Q=A[αKρ+(1α)Lρ]νρQ = A \left[ \alpha K^{-\rho} + (1-\alpha)L^{-\rho} \right]^{- \frac{\nu}{\rho}}

Where:

  • (Q) represents the total quantity of output produced.
  • (A) is the efficiency parameter, often representing the level of total factor productivity or technology.20
  • (\alpha) (alpha) is the distribution parameter, indicating the relative share of capital in production.
  • ((1-\alpha)) represents the relative share of labor.
  • (K) denotes the quantity of capital input.
  • (L) denotes the quantity of labor input.
  • (\rho) (rho) is the substitution parameter, which determines the elasticity of substitution ((\sigma)) between the inputs.19 The elasticity of substitution is calculated as (\sigma = \frac{1}{1+\rho}).
  • (\nu) (nu) is the degree of returns to scale. If (\nu = 1), the function exhibits constant returns to scale.18,17

This formula allows for a flexible representation of how easily capital and labor can be substituted for one another while maintaining the same level of output.

Interpreting the Constant Elasticity of Substitution Production Function

Interpreting the constant elasticity of substitution production function primarily revolves around understanding the substitution parameter, (\rho), and its derived elasticity of substitution ((\sigma)). A higher value of (\sigma) indicates that inputs are more easily substitutable. For instance, if (\sigma) approaches infinity (implying (\rho) approaches -1), inputs are perfect substitutes, meaning a firm could maintain output by completely replacing one input with another at a constant ratio. Conversely, if (\sigma) approaches zero (implying (\rho) approaches infinity), inputs are perfect complements, meaning they must be used in fixed proportions, and substituting one for the other is not possible without reducing output.,16

The flexibility of the CES production function allows economists to model diverse production technologies more accurately than simpler forms. For example, if the elasticity of substitution is found to be less than one, it suggests that increases in one input factor's relative price would lead to a more than proportional decrease in its usage relative to other inputs, highlighting specific constraints on resource allocation. Analyzing the shape of an isoquant derived from a CES function provides visual insight into this substitutability, showing the different combinations of inputs that yield the same level of output.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a manufacturing firm, "DiversiFab Inc.," that produces specialized components. Its output ((Q)) depends on the amount of capital ((K), e.g., machinery hours) and labor ((L), e.g., worker hours) it employs. DiversiFab's production can be modeled using a CES production function:

Q=10[0.4K0.5+0.6L0.5]10.5Q = 10 \left[ 0.4 K^{-0.5} + 0.6 L^{-0.5} \right]^{- \frac{1}{0.5}}

Here, (A = 10) (efficiency parameter), (\alpha = 0.4), (1-\alpha = 0.6), and (\rho = 0.5). The returns to scale (\nu) is implicitly 1.

First, calculate the elasticity of substitution:
(\sigma = \frac{1}{1+\rho} = \frac{1}{1+0.5} = \frac{1}{1.5} \approx 0.67).

This value of (\sigma) (less than 1) indicates that capital and labor are not easily substitutable for each other; they are complements to some degree.

Let's assume DiversiFab initially uses (K = 100) units of capital and (L = 100) units of labor.
Substituting these values into the function:

Q=10[0.4(100)0.5+0.6(100)0.5]10.5Q = 10 \left[ 0.4 (100)^{-0.5} + 0.6 (100)^{-0.5} \right]^{- \frac{1}{0.5}} Q=10[0.4(0.1)+0.6(0.1)]2Q = 10 \left[ 0.4 (0.1) + 0.6 (0.1) \right]^{-2} Q=10[0.04+0.06]2Q = 10 \left[ 0.04 + 0.06 \right]^{-2} Q=10[0.1]2Q = 10 \left[ 0.1 \right]^{-2} Q=10×100=1000Q = 10 \times 100 = 1000

So, with 100 units of capital and 100 units of labor, DiversiFab produces 1,000 components.

Now, suppose DiversiFab wants to maintain the same output level but has a decrease in available labor, say to (L = 80). Due to the limited substitutability ((\sigma \approx 0.67)), they would need a relatively larger increase in capital to compensate. This demonstrates how the CES production function helps firms understand the tradeoffs and optimal input mixes for desired output levels.

Practical Applications

The constant elasticity of substitution production function finds extensive use across various fields of economics and finance due to its flexibility in representing different technologies. In macroeconomics, it is frequently employed in economic growth models to analyze the drivers of output and productivity, helping to understand how changes in factor inputs and technological progress contribute to national income.15,14 For instance, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) utilizes production functions, including CES, in its analysis of productivity and factor allocation across member countries.13,12

Furthermore, the CES function is vital in analyzing factor income shares and their stability over time. Unlike simpler models, it allows for situations where the shares of income accruing to capital and labor are not fixed, providing a more realistic representation of dynamic economies.11 It is also applied in international trade theory to model how different countries allocate resources based on their relative factor endowments and the substitutability of inputs in their production processes. The function can also be instrumental in understanding the impact of policies that affect factor returns, such as various forms of taxation on capital and labor income.10

Limitations and Criticisms

Despite its versatility, the constant elasticity of substitution production function has certain limitations and has faced criticisms. One significant challenge lies in the empirical estimation of its parameters, particularly the elasticity of substitution. Econometric estimates can be inconsistent, making it difficult to precisely determine the true degree of substitutability between inputs in real-world scenarios.9 Some researchers argue that while the CES function is theoretically more general, its empirical superiority over simpler forms like the Cobb-Douglas production function is not always definitively established in all contexts.8

Another critique revolves around the assumption of a constant elasticity of substitution. In reality, the ease with which inputs can be substituted might change as the scale of production varies or as technological advancements occur. For instance, at very low or very high levels of input usage, the elasticity might differ. The challenges also extend to multi-factor models, where extending the CES functional form to accommodate more than two factors of production can lead to issues, as it may not always ensure constant elasticity among all pairs of factors simultaneously. Furthermore, the interpretation of the function's parameters, particularly the efficiency parameter, can be problematic without proper "normalization," which ensures these parameters have meaningful economic interpretation independent of the measurement units or the elasticity itself.7 Without appropriate normalization, the parameters of the CES production function can become dependent on the specific normalization point chosen, potentially undermining empirical estimation and comparative static analyses.6

Constant Elasticity of Substitution Production Function vs. Cobb-Douglas Production Function

The constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function and the Cobb-Douglas production function are both widely used in economics to model the relationship between inputs and output, but they differ fundamentally in their assumptions about factor substitutability.

FeatureConstant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) Production FunctionCobb-Douglas Production Function
Elasticity of SubstitutionAssumes a constant, but not necessarily unity, elasticity of substitution ((\sigma)).Assumes an elasticity of substitution exactly equal to one ((\sigma = 1)).
FlexibilityMore flexible, as it can model various degrees of substitutability between inputs.Less flexible, restricted to a specific degree of substitutability.
Factor SharesAllows for variable factor shares depending on relative input prices.Implies constant factor shares, regardless of changes in relative input prices.5,4
Mathematical FormGenerally more complex, involving summation of inputs raised to a negative power.Simpler, typically represented as a product of inputs raised to powers.
Special CaseThe Cobb-Douglas production function is a special limiting case of the CES function (when (\rho = 0), implying (\sigma = 1)).,3A specific instance within the broader family of CES functions.

The main point of confusion often arises because the Cobb-Douglas production function is a special case of the more general CES form. When the substitution parameter ((\rho)) in a CES function approaches zero, the CES function converges to the Cobb-Douglas function, implying that the elasticity of substitution is exactly one.,2 This means that for a Cobb-Douglas function, any change in the ratio of input prices is perfectly offset by a proportional change in the ratio of input quantities, keeping factor shares constant. In contrast, the CES function provides a richer framework to analyze economic phenomena where factor shares might fluctuate due to changes in relative factor costs.

FAQs

What does "constant elasticity of substitution" mean in a production function?

It means that the rate at which a firm can substitute one input factors, such as labor for capital, while maintaining the same level of output, remains unchanged regardless of how much of each input is already being used. This constant rate is quantified by the elasticity of substitution parameter.

How does the CES production function relate to technology?

The CES production function includes an efficiency parameter, often denoted as (A). This parameter reflects the level of technology or overall total factor productivity. An increase in (A) signifies a technological advancement, meaning the firm can produce more output with the same amount of inputs, or the same output with fewer inputs.

Can the CES production function show increasing or decreasing returns to scale?

Yes, the CES production function can exhibit increasing, decreasing, or constant returns to scale, depending on the value of its returns to scale parameter ((\nu)). If (\nu > 1), it shows increasing returns to scale; if (\nu < 1), decreasing returns; and if (\nu = 1), constant returns.

Why is the CES production function important in economic analysis?

The CES production function is important because it offers a more flexible and realistic representation of production processes compared to simpler models. By allowing the elasticity of substitution to be different from unity, it enables economists to better analyze how changes in factor prices affect the demand for inputs, factor income shares, and overall economic efficiency in various economic sectors and across different countries.

Is the CES production function always used in economic models?

While the CES production function is a powerful tool, it is not always used. Its complexity can sometimes be a drawback for simpler models or when empirical data does not strongly support a non-unity elasticity of substitution. In many applied macroeconomics models, the simpler Cobb-Douglas production function is still frequently employed, especially when its assumption of unitary elasticity of substitution is deemed a reasonable approximation or for analytical tractability.1