Skip to main content
← Back to E Definitions

Equity premium puzzle

What Is the Equity Premium Puzzle?

The equity premium puzzle refers to the persistent empirical observation that the historical average return on stocks has been significantly higher than the average return on relatively less risky assets, such as U.S. Treasury bills. This disparity, which seems too large to be explained by conventional economic models that account for investor risk aversion alone, falls under the broader field of financial economics and asset pricing theory. Despite extensive research, the magnitude of this historical outperformance, known as the equity risk premium, has presented a considerable challenge to standard models, thus earning it the moniker "puzzle." The equity premium puzzle implies that investors demand a much greater compensation for holding equities than theoretical models would predict, considering the level of risk involved.

History and Origin

The concept of the equity premium puzzle was formally introduced by economists Rajnish Mehra and Edward C. Prescott in their seminal 1985 paper, "The Equity Premium: A Puzzle."35, 36 Their study examined U.S. financial market data from 1889 to 1978 and found that the average real annual return on stocks, represented by the Standard & Poor 500 Index, was approximately 7%, while the average real return on short-term debt was less than 1%. This substantial difference—a premium of over 6 percentage points—was far greater than what could be rationalized by prevailing economic models, particularly the Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model (CCAPM). Meh34ra and Prescott demonstrated that for standard models to account for such a large equity premium, investors would need to exhibit an implausibly high degree of risk aversion, which contradicted other economic observations about consumer behavior and utility function preferences. The32, 33 publication of their paper ignited decades of research within academic and financial communities, seeking to resolve this perplexing discrepancy.

##31 Key Takeaways

  • The equity premium puzzle highlights the historical observation that stocks have significantly outperformed lower-risk assets like government bonds by a margin that is difficult to justify with standard economic theory.
  • It was formally identified by Rajnish Mehra and Edward C. Prescott in their influential 1985 paper.
  • The puzzle suggests that investors exhibit a higher degree of risk aversion towards equities than conventional models typically assume.
  • Proposed explanations include behavioral biases, market imperfections, rare disaster events, and various modifications to investor preferences or market structures.
  • Despite numerous attempts, a universally accepted solution to the equity premium puzzle remains elusive.

Formula and Calculation

While the equity premium puzzle itself describes the discrepancy between observed and theoretically predicted equity returns, the core measurement involved is the equity risk premium. The historical equity risk premium is calculated as the difference between the average historical return of a broad market index (representing equity returns) and the average historical return of a virtually risk-free asset, such as short-term government debt.

[29](https://www.soa.org/newsandpublications/newsletters/pensionsectionnews/2013/may/psn2013iss80/equityriskpremiums/),[30](https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=VinQHQrGN8)Equity Risk Premium (ERP)=Average Equity ReturnAverage Risk-Free Rate[^29^](https://www.soa.org/news-and-publications/newsletters/pension-section-news/2013/may/psn-2013-iss80/equity-risk-premiums/), [^30^](https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=VinQHQrGN-8) \text{Equity Risk Premium (ERP)} = \text{Average Equity Return} - \text{Average Risk-Free Rate}

Where:

  • (\text{Average Equity Return}) is the average realized return from a diversified portfolio of stocks over a specific period. This often uses broad market indices like the S&P 500.
  • 28 (\text{Average Risk-Free Rate}) is the average return on a theoretical asset with no default risk and no price variation, commonly proxied by the yield on short-term U.S. Treasury bills.

Fo27r example, Mehra and Prescott noted that for the period 1889-1978, the average real return on U.S. stocks was 6.98% per year, while the average real return on bills was 0.80% per year. Thi26s resulted in an equity risk premium of 6.18 percentage points. The "puzzle" arises because this empirically observed premium is considerably larger than what rational economic models, which consider factors like consumption smoothing, would predict.

##25 Interpreting the Equity Premium Puzzle

Interpreting the equity premium puzzle involves understanding that the observed historical equity risk premium is higher than what can be explained by traditional economic models that assume rational investors with standard preferences. In essence, it implies that investors have historically demanded, and received, a much larger compensation for bearing the risk of equity investments than theory suggests they should. Thi24s suggests that either the assumed level of risk tolerance in these models is too low, or there are other significant factors influencing market behavior that are not fully captured by the models.

For instance, if investors were truly as risk-averse as the equity premium implies, they should have significantly reduced their allocation to stocks and increased their holdings of safer assets. However, this level of implied risk aversion often contradicts other observed economic phenomena and patterns of saving and investment. The22, 23 puzzle therefore challenges fundamental assumptions about how financial markets operate and how individuals make investment decisions, suggesting a gap in our understanding of the true drivers of asset returns.

##20, 21 Hypothetical Example

Consider a hypothetical investment scenario where two assets are available: a broad market stock index and a risk-free Treasury bill.

  • Stock Index: Over the last 50 years, the average annual real return has been 7.0%.
  • Treasury Bills: Over the same 50 years, the average annual real return has been 1.5%.

Based on these historical figures, the observed equity risk premium is:

ERP=7.0%1.5%=5.5%\text{ERP} = 7.0\% - 1.5\% = 5.5\%

Now, imagine a theoretical economic model, such as the Consumption Capital Asset Pricing Model (CCAPM), designed to predict asset returns based on factors like aggregate consumption growth and a reasonable degree of investor risk aversion. This model, when calibrated with typical economic parameters, might predict an equity risk premium of only 0.5% to 1.0%.

Th19e hypothetical example illustrates the equity premium puzzle: a historically observed 5.5% equity premium vastly exceeds the 0.5% to 1.0% premium predicted by the theoretical model. This significant discrepancy between the actual returns investors have earned on equities versus the theoretically expected compensation for risk is precisely what constitutes the puzzle. It challenges economists to explain why investors appear to demand such a substantial premium for holding a diversified portfolio of stocks, given the relatively smooth nature of aggregate consumption over time.

Practical Applications

While the equity premium puzzle remains an academic challenge, understanding its implications has several practical applications in investing and financial analysis.

Firstly, it influences how financial professionals and investors approach long-term expected returns for different asset classes. Despite the puzzle's existence, historical data consistently show stocks outperforming bonds over extended periods, leading many to factor a positive equity risk premium into their capital market expectations. For example, Schwab Asset Management's long-term forecasts continue to highlight opportunities in fixed income while noting that equities face a narrowing, though still positive, edge over "risk-free" investments due to factors like elevated bond yields. Thi18s perspective is crucial for setting realistic investment goals and designing strategic asset allocation strategies.

Secondly, the puzzle prompts ongoing research into factors beyond simple risk-return tradeoffs that might influence asset prices. This includes exploring the roles of behavioral finance, such as loss aversion and myopic behavior, which suggest that psychological biases may lead investors to demand a higher premium for stocks than traditional models account for. Thi17s broader understanding can help investors and analysts recognize potential deviations from purely rational market behavior.

Finally, insights from the equity premium puzzle contribute to the development of more sophisticated valuation models and capital budgeting decisions. By attempting to resolve the puzzle, economists refine their understanding of the true cost of equity, which is a critical input for corporate finance decisions and valuing businesses. Researchers at institutions like the Federal Reserve Board also study the global determinants of equity risk premiums, acknowledging their importance as indicators of economic and financial market uncertainties.

##15, 16 Limitations and Criticisms

Despite its prominence, the equity premium puzzle faces several limitations and criticisms, reflecting the complexity of explaining long-term financial market phenomena. One significant critique revolves around the choice of the "risk-free asset" and the time period used for analysis. Some argue that U.S. historical data, particularly post-World War II, might be an anomaly, representing an unusually stable and prosperous period that exaggerates the true long-term global equity premium. Ind14eed, studies examining longer historical periods or international data sometimes find a smaller premium or even periods where bonds outperformed stocks. The12, 13 Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, for instance, has explored a "total risk premium puzzle" that incorporates housing returns, suggesting an even larger discrepancy in implied risk aversion when considering a broader portfolio of risky assets beyond just equities.

An10, 11other area of criticism targets the assumptions within the traditional economic models, particularly the constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) preferences. Critics argue that these models might not fully capture the nuanced decision-making of investors, who may exhibit time-varying risk aversion or be more sensitive to downside risks. For8, 9 example, the concept of "myopic loss aversion," which combines investors' tendency to be more sensitive to losses than gains with frequent evaluations of their portfolios, has been proposed as a behavioral explanation for the puzzle. This perspective suggests that the arbitrage opportunity presented by the large equity premium is not fully exploited due to psychological factors.

Furthermore, some academics contend that the equity premium puzzle may be, in part, a statistical illusion or a result of specific data aggregation methods. They question whether the high historical premium is truly "unexplained" or if it reflects factors like infrequent but severe economic "disasters" that are not adequately captured in standard models. Whi7le significant progress has been made, a universally agreed-upon resolution that fully reconciles the historically observed equity premium with plausible economic theory remains elusive.

Equity Premium Puzzle vs. Equity Risk Premium

The terms "equity premium puzzle" and "equity risk premium" are closely related but refer to distinct concepts.

The equity risk premium (ERP) is a measurable financial metric. It represents the actual or expected difference between the return on equities (stocks) and the return on a risk-free asset (such as government bonds or Treasury bills). It quantifies the additional compensation investors demand or receive for taking on the higher risk associated with stock investments compared to safer assets. The5, 6 ERP can be calculated historically (realized ERP) or estimated for the future (expected ERP).

The equity premium puzzle, on the other hand, is not a metric but a theoretical dilemma or anomaly within financial economics. It specifically refers to the observation that the historical equity risk premium has been significantly larger than what can be justified by standard economic models of rational investor behavior and risk aversion. The puzzle highlights the unexplained gap between the empirically observed ERP and the ERP predicted by these theoretical models, suggesting that the traditional framework may be incomplete or that investor behavior deviates from pure rationality. Therefore, while the equity risk premium is the empirical observation, the equity premium puzzle is the challenge of explaining its magnitude within conventional economic theory.

FAQs

Why is the equity premium considered a "puzzle"?

It's considered a "puzzle" because the historically observed difference between stock returns and risk-free returns (the equity risk premium) is much larger than what standard economic models can explain, assuming a reasonable level of investor rationality and risk aversion. The4se models predict a much smaller premium for bearing equity risk.

Who first identified the equity premium puzzle?

The equity premium puzzle was formally identified and popularized by economists Rajnish Mehra and Edward C. Prescott in their 1985 paper, "The Equity Premium: A Puzzle."

##3# What are some proposed solutions to the equity premium puzzle?
Many explanations have been proposed, including behavioral finance theories (e.g., loss aversion, myopic behavior), market imperfections (e.g., borrowing constraints, transaction costs), and models incorporating rare but severe economic disasters. However, no single explanation has fully resolved the puzzle to universal satisfaction.

Does the equity premium puzzle mean stocks are always a better investment than bonds?

The equity premium puzzle highlights a historical trend where stocks have offered higher returns than bonds over long periods. However, it does not guarantee future performance. There have been periods where bonds have outperformed stocks, and investment outcomes depend on various factors, including market conditions, time horizons, and individual financial goals.

##2# How does the equity premium puzzle relate to modern portfolio theory?
The equity premium puzzle challenges some fundamental assumptions underlying traditional modern portfolio theory and capital asset pricing models. It suggests that the premium for bearing systematic risk might be higher than these models predict, or that other forms of risk or behavioral factors play a more significant role in determining asset returns than previously understood.1