Skip to main content
← Back to F Definitions

Free rider

LINK_POOL:

Anchor TextURL
public goods
market failurehttps://diversification.com/term/market_failure
collective action
externalitieshttps://diversification.com/term/externalities
rational choice theory
tragedy of the commons
game theoryhttps://diversification.com/term/game_theory
Prisoner's Dilemma
private goods
taxationhttps://diversification.com/term/taxation
subsidies
moral hazard
adverse selection
transaction costs
behavioral economicshttps://diversification.com/term/behavioral_economics

What Is Free Rider?

A free rider is an individual or entity that benefits from a resource, good, or service without contributing to its cost. This phenomenon is a core concept in economic theory, particularly within the study of public goods and collective action, and often leads to what is known as a market failure. The problem arises because public goods are generally non-excludable, meaning it is difficult to prevent individuals from consuming them even if they haven't paid, and non-rivalrous, meaning one person's consumption does not diminish its availability for others.38, 39 When too many people choose to free ride, the essential funding or effort required to produce and maintain these collective resources may not be sufficiently raised, potentially leading to their under-provision or even complete absence.36, 37

History and Origin

The concept of the free rider problem gained widespread recognition and academic prominence following the publication of Mancur Olson's seminal 1965 book, "The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups." Olson's work challenged prevailing assumptions that individuals in large groups would naturally act collectively to achieve common interests. Instead, he argued that rational individuals in large groups would have an incentive to free ride on the efforts of others, as they could enjoy the benefits without bearing the costs.33, 34, 35 This perspective shed light on various societal issues, moving the understanding of free riding from an exception to a standard behavior in specific circumstances.31, 32 Before Olson, variations of the problem had been discussed in social science, particularly in the context of group dynamics since at least World War II.29, 30

Key Takeaways

  • A free rider is someone who benefits from a good or service without contributing to its cost.
  • The free rider problem primarily occurs with public goods, which are non-excludable and non-rivalrous.
  • This behavior can lead to the under-provision or non-provision of socially beneficial goods and services.
  • It highlights a significant challenge in collective action and can result in market failure.
  • Solutions often involve government intervention, such as taxation or regulation, or the implementation of selective incentives.

Interpreting the Free Rider

The free rider problem is interpreted as a challenge to the efficient allocation of resources and the provision of public goods. In situations where free riding is prevalent, the market mechanism fails to provide an optimal level of the good because individuals lack sufficient incentive to contribute.26, 27, 28 This often means that socially desirable outcomes, such as clean air or national defense, are under-supplied if left purely to voluntary contributions.24, 25 The extent of free riding can indicate the degree to which a public good is prone to this issue, often tied to the group size and the costs of exclusion. The free rider problem is a key component of understanding various economic and social dilemmas, including the tragedy of the commons, where shared resources are depleted due to individual self-interest.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a neighborhood park. All residents benefit from its existence, enjoying green space, recreational facilities, and a pleasant environment. The maintenance of this park—mowing lawns, repairing equipment, picking up trash—requires funds. If the neighborhood association relies solely on voluntary donations, some residents might choose not to contribute, assuming others will cover the costs. These non-contributing residents are free riders. They still enjoy the benefits of the well-maintained park without bearing any of the financial burden. If a significant number of residents adopt this free-riding behavior, the association may not collect enough money to maintain the park, leading to its deterioration. This illustrates how individual rational choices, when aggregated, can lead to a suboptimal collective outcome and a classic example of the free rider problem affecting community resources.

Practical Applications

The free rider problem manifests across various domains, impacting investment, markets, regulation, and public planning. In environmental regulation, addressing global warming is a classic example, as all countries benefit from a stable climate, but the cost of reducing carbon emissions is substantial. Without coordinated efforts, some nations might free ride on the emissions reduction efforts of others. Sim23ilarly, public broadcasting services often rely on government subsidies or voluntary donations, and the free rider problem occurs when many listeners consume these services without contributing financially.

In22 the context of investing, the free rider concept can apply to situations where investors benefit from market transparency and regulatory oversight without actively supporting the mechanisms that provide them. For instance, regulations from bodies like the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) provide investor protection and maintain fair markets, but the costs of enforcing these regulations are borne by taxpayers and regulated entities. Another area is research and development (R&D) in industries like pharmaceuticals, where the benefits of a new drug, once developed, can spill over to competitors who did not bear the R&D costs, potentially disincentivizing private investment without intellectual property protection.

Limitations and Criticisms

While the free rider problem provides a powerful framework for understanding collective action challenges, it faces several limitations and criticisms. One critique centers on the assumption of purely self-interested rational choice theory. Some argue that individuals are not always perfectly rational or solely driven by self-interest and may contribute to public goods due to social pressures, moral obligations, or a desire for reciprocity, even without direct selective incentives. Res19, 20, 21earch in behavioral economics, for example, explores how factors beyond pure economic rationality influence cooperative behavior.

An18other limitation is the oversimplification of "public goods." Critics suggest that the strict definitions of non-excludability and non-rivalry may not apply to all collectively provided goods, and that mechanisms for exclusion or rivalry can sometimes be developed or already exist. Fur17thermore, the free rider problem is often presented as a justification for government intervention through taxation or regulation. How15, 16ever, some argue that this approach can lead to inefficiencies or that alternative solutions, such as community-based initiatives or private provision with selective incentives, may be more effective in certain contexts. The13, 14 problem also becomes more acute in very large groups, where an individual's contribution seems negligible, but can be less severe in smaller groups where individual contributions are more visible and impactful.

##12 Free Rider vs. Moral Hazard

The terms "free rider" and "moral hazard" are distinct concepts in economics, though both relate to situations where individuals might alter their behavior due to a lack of accountability or shared costs.

A free rider benefits from a good or service without contributing to its cost, typically because the good is non-excludable. The core issue is the under-provision of public goods because individuals can enjoy them for "free." For example, someone who enjoys a public fireworks display without contributing to its funding is a free rider.

11Moral hazard, on the other hand, describes a situation where one party takes on more risk because another party bears the cost of that risk. This often arises in insurance or principal-agent relationships. For instance, if a company's executives are insured against all losses, they might take on excessively risky projects, knowing the insurer will cover potential failures. The problem here is the change in behavior after an agreement or arrangement is made, leading to increased risk exposure for the party bearing the cost. While a free rider avoids a cost upfront, moral hazard involves a shift in behavior that increases costs or risks for others after a cost-bearing arrangement is in place.

FAQs

What is the primary characteristic of goods that lead to the free rider problem?

The primary characteristics are non-excludability and non-rivalry. Non-excludability means it's difficult to prevent people from consuming the good even if they don't pay, while non-rivalry means one person's use doesn't reduce its availability for others.

##9, 10# How does the free rider problem affect the provision of public goods?

The free rider problem leads to the under-provision or non-provision of public goods. Because individuals can benefit without contributing, there is a reduced incentive for anyone to pay for or produce the good, resulting in a quantity lower than what would be socially optimal.

##6, 7, 8# Can the free rider problem be solved without government intervention?

While government intervention, such as taxation or regulation, is a common solution, the free rider problem can sometimes be addressed through other means. These include social pressures, community-based solutions, and the use of selective incentives or private goods to encourage contributions to a larger collective action.

##3, 4, 5# Is the free rider problem always considered negative?

In economic theory, the free rider problem is generally considered negative because it leads to market failure and the under-provision of socially beneficial goods. However, in some contexts, certain "free rider" activities, like benefiting from general knowledge dissemination, are not necessarily harmful and can even foster innovation, though they don't fit the typical definition of the problem leading to under-provision.

##2# What is an example of a free rider in daily life?

A common example is someone who benefits from public street lighting without paying local taxes that fund it. Everyone in the area receives the benefit of illuminated streets, regardless of their individual tax contributions, creating a potential free rider scenario.1