Skip to main content
← Back to G Definitions

Growth models

What Are Growth Models?

Growth models are theoretical frameworks used in finance and economics to explain and predict changes in variables such as a company's earnings, stock prices, or a nation's gross domestic product. These models fall under the broader category of financial economics and macroeconomics, providing structured approaches to understand the dynamics of expansion and development. Growth models serve as essential tools for investors, policymakers, and analysts seeking to project future performance and make informed decisions. By analyzing various inputs, these models offer insights into sustainable growth paths and potential future values.

History and Origin

The concept of modeling growth has roots in both macroeconomic theory and corporate finance. In macroeconomics, one of the most influential growth models is the Solow-Swan model, independently developed by Robert Solow and Trevor Swan in 1956. This model provided a foundational framework for understanding long-term economic growth by emphasizing factors like capital accumulation, labor growth, and technological progress. It built upon earlier work like the Harrod-Domar model by incorporating a neoclassical production function, allowing for variable capital-output ratios.10,9,

In corporate finance, a prominent growth model is the Gordon Growth Model (GGM), also known as the Gordon-Shapiro Model. Myron J. Gordon and Eli Shapiro introduced this model in the early 1960s as an extension of John Burr Williams' Dividend Discount Model from the 1930s.8 The GGM gained popularity for its simplicity in valuing stocks based on the assumption of a constant dividend growth rate.7

Key Takeaways

  • Growth models provide structured frameworks for forecasting financial and economic expansion.
  • The Solow-Swan model explains macroeconomic growth based on capital, labor, and technology.
  • The Gordon Growth Model is a widely used financial model for stock valuation based on future dividends.
  • These models are crucial for financial analysis and strategic planning.
  • Understanding the assumptions and limitations of each growth model is vital for accurate interpretation.

Formula and Calculation

The Gordon Growth Model (GGM) is a widely used financial growth model to calculate the intrinsic value of a stock. It assumes that dividends grow at a constant rate indefinitely.

The formula is expressed as:

P=D1rgP = \frac{D_1}{r - g}

Where:

  • ( P ) = Current market price of the stock (or intrinsic value)
  • ( D_1 ) = Expected dividend per share in the next period
  • ( r ) = Required rate of return (or discount rate)
  • ( g ) = Constant growth rate of dividends in perpetuity

This formula calculates the present value of an infinite series of future dividends.

Interpreting Growth Models

Interpreting growth models requires careful consideration of their underlying assumptions and the context in which they are applied. For the Gordon Growth Model, a higher expected dividend growth rate ((g)) or a lower required rate of return ((r)) will result in a higher calculated intrinsic value for the stock. Conversely, if the required rate of return is too close to or less than the growth rate, the model yields an unrealistic or undefined value, highlighting a critical limitation. This suggests that the model is best suited for mature companies with stable, predictable dividend growth rates.

In macroeconomics, the Solow-Swan model's interpretation focuses on the concept of a steady state. This is an equilibrium where capital per worker and output per worker remain constant, with sustained per capita growth only possible through ongoing technological progress.6 An economy starting below its steady state will grow faster as it accumulates capital, while one above it will see growth slow. The model implies that while increased savings can boost the standard of living in the short run, long-term per capita growth ultimately depends on innovation.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a hypothetical company, "GreenTech Innovations," that paid a dividend of $1.50 per share last year. Analysts expect its dividends to grow at a constant rate of 4% per year indefinitely. An investor requires a 10% rate of return for similar investment opportunities.

To use the Gordon Growth Model:

  1. Calculate the expected dividend for the next period ((D_1)):
    ( D_1 = D_0 \times (1 + g) = $1.50 \times (1 + 0.04) = $1.56 )
  2. Apply the Gordon Growth Model formula:
    P=$1.560.100.04P = \frac{\$1.56}{0.10 - 0.04}
    P=$1.560.06P = \frac{\$1.56}{0.06}
    P=$26.00P = \$26.00

Based on this growth model, the intrinsic value of GreenTech Innovations' stock for this investor is $26.00. If the stock's current market price is below $26.00, it might be considered undervalued based on this analysis.

Practical Applications

Growth models find practical application across various sectors of finance and economics. In corporate finance, the Gordon Growth Model is frequently employed by analysts to estimate the fair value of dividend-paying stocks, helping investors decide whether a stock is overvalued or undervalued.5 It serves as a foundational component in many dividend discount model variations.

On a broader scale, macroeconomic growth models, like the Solow-Swan model and its extensions, are critical for national economic planning and policy formulation. Governments and international organizations utilize these models to project future economic activity, understand the drivers of prosperity, and formulate policies related to fiscal policy, investment, and innovation. For instance, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) regularly publishes global growth forecasts, providing an outlook on the world economy and individual nations based on complex models that consider various growth factors.4 Such projections inform global trade policies and international capital flows.

Limitations and Criticisms

While growth models provide valuable insights, they come with inherent limitations and are subject to criticism. The Gordon Growth Model, for example, relies heavily on several restrictive assumptions: it assumes a constant dividend growth rate into perpetuity, which is rarely realistic for companies over very long periods. It also assumes that the required rate of return ((r)) must be greater than the dividend growth rate ((g)); if (r \le g), the formula produces an undefined or negative value, rendering it unusable.3, Furthermore, the model is unsuitable for companies that do not pay dividends or those with erratic dividend histories. Critics like Aswath Damodaran acknowledge the Dividend Discount Model's theoretical foundation but highlight its practical challenges in estimating inputs like future growth rates and required returns accurately.2

Macroeconomic growth models, such as the Solow-Swan model, have been critiqued for their exogenous treatment of technological progress—meaning technology is assumed to improve independently rather than being driven by economic forces. This simplification can limit their ability to fully explain sustained long-term growth differences between countries. Additionally, these models typically assume a closed economy and perfect competition, which may not hold true in the complex global economy. Real-world factors like geopolitical tensions, trade tariffs, and unforeseen economic shocks can significantly alter growth trajectories, as evidenced by fluctuations in global economic outlooks.

1## Growth Models vs. Valuation Models

While "growth models" and "valuation models" are closely related and often overlap, they serve distinct primary purposes. Growth models, in a general sense, are analytical tools designed to predict or explain the expansion of a variable over time. This can refer to anything from a company's earnings per share to a nation's total output. Their focus is on the rate and drivers of increase.

Valuation models, conversely, are specifically used to determine the intrinsic or fair value of an asset, security, or business. They often incorporate elements of growth to project future cash flows or earnings, which are then discounted back to their present value. The Gordon Growth Model is an excellent example of a growth model used within a broader valuation framework, specifically the Dividend Discount Model. While the GGM predicts a stock's price based on dividend growth, its ultimate goal is valuation. Other valuation models, such as discounted cash flow (DCF) models, might use different methods to project future cash flows, but the concept of growth remains central to their calculations. The key distinction lies in the primary objective: growth models explain or forecast expansion, while valuation models quantify worth.

FAQs

What is the primary purpose of a growth model?

The primary purpose of a growth model is to provide a framework for understanding and predicting how a specific variable, such as a company's dividends or a country's economic output, will increase over time. They help in forecasting future performance.

Can growth models be used for any company?

No. Financial growth models like the Gordon Growth Model are best suited for companies with a history of stable and predictable dividend payments, or at least a clear path to consistent future growth. They are generally not ideal for startups or companies with volatile earnings and no dividend payout.

What is the role of technology in macroeconomic growth models?

In many macroeconomic growth models, such as the Solow-Swan model, technological progress is a crucial factor for sustained long-term growth in per capita output and living standards. Without technological advancements, economies tend to reach a steady state where growth eventually stalls.

How do interest rates affect growth models?

In financial growth models like the Gordon Growth Model, the required rate of return, which is influenced by prevailing interest rates and the perceived risk of an investment, is a key input. Higher interest rates typically lead to a higher required rate of return, which can reduce the calculated intrinsic value of an asset.

Are growth models always accurate?

No, growth models are based on assumptions about future conditions, which may not always hold true. Their accuracy depends heavily on the quality of inputs and the validity of their underlying assumptions. They are analytical tools that provide estimates, not guarantees.