Skip to main content
← Back to H Definitions

Hicksian demand function

What Is Hicksian Demand Function?

The Hicksian demand function, also known as compensated demand, represents the quantity of a good a consumer would demand to minimize their total expenditure while maintaining a constant level of utility. This fundamental concept in microeconomics, specifically within consumer theory, isolates the impact of a price change on consumer choices by eliminating the "income effect." In essence, the Hicksian demand function reveals how a consumer's desired consumption bundle adjusts solely due to changes in relative prices, assuming their income is hypothetically adjusted—or compensated—to keep their overall satisfaction level unchanged. It is a cornerstone for understanding deeper aspects of consumer behavior and how individuals make optimal choices under various economic conditions.

History and Origin

The Hicksian demand function is named after Sir John R. Hicks, a prominent British economist who significantly contributed to modern economic theory. Hicks introduced the concept of compensated demand in his seminal 1939 work, Value and Capital. In this influential book, Hicks advanced the theory of consumer choice by developing the indifference curve analysis, which provided a robust framework for understanding consumer preferences without relying on the assumption of measurable utility.

Hi24cks’s work sought to decompose the total effect of a price change on quantity demanded into two distinct components: the substitution effect and the income effect. While23 earlier economists like Alfred Marshall focused on demand functions that implicitly included both effects, Hicks's innovation was to isolate the substitution effect by theorizing a demand function where the consumer's real income (or utility level) remained constant despite price changes. This 22allowed for a more precise understanding of how consumers substitute goods when relative prices shift. The Cato Institute highlights that Hicks's theory of utility proved more useful than alternatives partly because it cleanly decomposes the effect of a price change into these two components.

K21ey Takeaways

  • Constant Utility: The Hicksian demand function illustrates the quantity of goods demanded when a consumer's utility level is held constant, even as prices change.
  • Expenditure Minimization: It is derived from the problem of minimizing expenditure required to achieve a specific level of utility.
  • Isolates Substitution Effect: This function is crucial for isolating the substitution effect of a price change, showing how consumers adjust consumption based purely on relative price shifts.
  • Theoretical Tool: The Hicksian demand function is primarily a theoretical construct used in welfare economics and advanced microeconomic analysis to understand consumer responses to price changes more deeply.
  • Compensated Demand: It is also referred to as "compensated demand" because it assumes the consumer is compensated with enough income to maintain their original utility level after a price change.

Formula and Calculation

The Hicksian demand function, denoted as (h(p, \bar{u})), is derived from the consumer's expenditure minimization problem. It represents the quantity (x_i) of good (i) that a consumer demands when facing a vector of prices (p) and aiming to achieve a predetermined minimum level of utility (\bar{u}).

Mathematically, the Hicksian demand function for a bundle of goods (x = (x_1, x_2, \dots, x_n)) at a given price vector (p = (p_1, p_2, \dots, p_n)) and utility level (\bar{u}) is defined as:

h(p,uˉ)=argminxi=1npixisubject to U(x)uˉh(p, \bar{u}) = \arg \min_{x} \sum_{i=1}^{n} p_i x_i \\ \text{subject to } U(x) \ge \bar{u}

Where:

  • (h(p, \bar{u})) is the Hicksian demand function, yielding the vector of quantities (x) demanded.
  • (p_i) is the price of good (i).
  • (x_i) is the quantity of good (i).
  • (\sum_{i=1}^{n} p_i x_i) is the total expenditure on all goods.
  • (U(x)) is the consumer's utility function, representing the satisfaction derived from consuming the bundle (x).
  • (\bar{u}) is the fixed target level of utility.

This formulation ensures that the consumer chooses the least costly bundle of goods that provides at least the specified level of satisfaction, effectively holding utility constant and isolating the pure effect of price changes on consumption patterns.

Interpreting the Hicksian Demand Function

The core interpretation of the Hicksian demand function lies in its ability to isolate the pure substitution effect of a price change. When the price of a good changes, a consumer's real purchasing power is also affected, leading to an income effect. The Hicksian demand function removes this income effect by conceptually "compensating" the consumer with enough income to keep them on their original indifference curve, thus maintaining their initial level of utility.

Ther20efore, any change in the quantity demanded along a Hicksian demand curve is solely attributable to the change in the relative attractiveness of the goods. If the price of Good A increases, the Hicksian demand for Good A will decrease (assuming it's a normal good) because it has become relatively more expensive compared to other goods, prompting the consumer to substitute towards alternatives, while remaining at the same utility level. This isolation is crucial for economists to understand consumer responsiveness to price changes without the confounding influence of altered purchasing power. It helps in analyzing concepts like price elasticity in a more refined manner.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a consumer, Sarah, who derives utility from consuming two goods: coffee and bagels. Initially, coffee costs $3 and bagels cost $2, and Sarah chooses a combination that gives her a specific level of utility, say 100 "utils."

Now, imagine the price of coffee increases to $4.
According to the Hicksian demand function, we want to know how Sarah's consumption of coffee and bagels would change if she were compensated with enough income to still achieve her original utility level of 100 utils, despite the higher coffee price.

  1. Initial Equilibrium: Sarah is on an indifference curve representing 100 utils, consuming a certain combination of coffee and bagels that minimizes her expenditure at the initial prices.
  2. Price Change & Compensation: The price of coffee rises. To keep Sarah's utility at 100, we hypothetically give her additional income. This compensation is precisely enough to offset the loss in purchasing power from the coffee price increase, allowing her to stay on her original indifference curve.
  3. New Hicksian Demand: With this compensated income, Sarah re-evaluates her consumption. Since coffee is now relatively more expensive (even with the compensation), she will likely reduce her consumption of coffee and increase her consumption of bagels, not because she has less purchasing power, but purely because bagels are now relatively cheaper. The Hicksian demand for coffee at the new price of $4 and the original utility level of 100 utils would reflect this new, purely substitution-driven quantity. This allows economists to understand how preferences for these goods are affected by relative price changes, without conflating it with income effects.

Practical Applications

The Hicksian demand function, while abstract, has significant practical applications in various areas of economics and policy analysis:

  • Welfare Economics and Policy Analysis: It is extensively used in welfare economics to evaluate the impact of government policies like taxes and subsidies on consumer well-being. By isolating the substitution effect, policymakers can measure the "true" cost or benefit of a policy, distinct from how it affects real income. For example, when a government imposes a tax on a good, the Hicksian demand function helps to determine the pure welfare loss (deadweight loss) associated with consumers shifting their consumption patterns due to the relative price change, as well as the distributional effects of the tax. Simil19arly, for subsidies on essential goods, it helps fine-tune policy to ensure intended utility protection.
  • 18Measuring Consumer Surplus: Hicksian demand curves are critical for calculating precise measures of welfare changes, such as compensating variation and equivalent variation, which quantify how much income a consumer would need to be compensated or would be willing to pay to maintain their utility level after a price change.
  • 17Analyzing Market Behavior: By providing a framework to model consumer behavior under varying conditions, the Hicksian demand function contributes to more accurate predictions of how consumers respond to price changes. This helps businesses and policymakers forecast market adjustments and refine strategies.
  • 1615Economic Modeling: Incorporating the Hicksian demand function into broader economic models allows for a more accurate capture of consumer responses when policies affecting relative prices are implemented, such as trade tariffs or price controls. This 14enhanced understanding aids in developing more effective economic policies by predicting consumer choices precisely.

L13imitations and Criticisms

Despite its theoretical elegance and practical applications, the Hicksian demand function faces certain limitations and criticisms:

  • Difficulty in Estimation: In practical applications, estimating a consumer's true utility function and, by extension, the Hicksian demand function, can be challenging. Directly observing and quantifying utility levels in the real world is difficult, which affects the accuracy of real-world calculations.
  • 12Simplifying Assumptions: The theory often relies on simplifying assumptions, such as consumers having perfect information and making perfectly rational decisions with consistent preferences over time. In re11ality, consumer behavior can be influenced by emotions, social factors, and imperfect information, which the Hicksian model does not explicitly account for.
  • 10Static Analysis: Traditional Hicksian models are primarily static, meaning they do not easily account for dynamic market conditions, such as evolving tastes, changing income levels over time, or consumer expectations and uncertainties. This 9static nature may limit its explanatory power for long-term trends or rapid shifts in demand patterns.
  • 8Focus on Individual vs. Aggregate: While powerful for individual consumer analysis, aggregating Hicksian demand functions to represent market demand can be complex, especially when dealing with diverse consumer preferences and income distributions. The theory generally assumes a fixed budget constraint for the consumer, overlooking the impact of changes in income distribution on overall demand.

H7icksian Demand Function vs. Marshallian Demand Function

The Hicksian demand function and the Marshallian demand function are both fundamental concepts in demand theory, but they differ critically in how they treat changes in consumer welfare or income when prices change.

The Marshallian demand function (also known as ordinary or uncompensated demand) shows the quantity of a good a consumer demands as its price changes, assuming the consumer's money income remains constant. This means the Marshallian demand curve incorporates both the substitution effect (due to changes in relative prices) and the income effect (due to changes in purchasing power). It is derived from the consumer's utility maximization problem, where the consumer maximizes utility subject to a fixed budget.

In c6ontrast, the Hicksian demand function (or compensated demand) shows the quantity of a good a consumer demands as its price changes, assuming their level of utility remains constant. To achieve this, any change in real income resulting from a price change is hypothetically "compensated" for, ensuring the consumer remains on the same indifference curve. There5fore, the Hicksian demand function isolates only the substitution effect. The core distinction is that Marshallian demand holds income constant, while Hicksian demand holds utility constant. The relationship between these two demand functions is formally described by the Slutsky equation, which mathematically decomposes the total price effect into the substitution and income effects.

FAQs

What is the primary purpose of the Hicksian demand function?

The primary purpose of the Hicksian demand function is to isolate the pure substitution effect of a price change on consumer demand. It shows how a consumer would adjust their consumption purely due to a change in relative prices, assuming their satisfaction level (utility) remains constant.

4How does "compensated demand" relate to the Hicksian demand function?

"Compensated demand" is another name for the Hicksian demand function. This terminology arises because the model conceptually "compensates" the consumer for any change in their real income or purchasing power that occurs due to a price change, ensuring they remain at the same level of utility.

3Why is Hicksian demand useful in welfare economics?

The Hicksian demand function is useful in welfare economics because it allows economists and policymakers to precisely measure the welfare impact of price changes resulting from taxes, subsidies, or other market interventions. By focusing on constant utility, it helps to quantify changes in consumer well-being through concepts like compensating variation, providing a clearer picture of who gains or loses and by how much.

2What is the difference between Hicksian and Marshallian demand in terms of what they hold constant?

The key difference is what is held constant: the Hicksian demand function holds utility (or real income) constant, isolating the substitution effect. The Marshallian demand function holds money income constant, thus incorporating both the substitution and income effect of a price change.

1Is the Hicksian demand function always downward sloping?

Yes, for normal goods, the Hicksian demand function is always downward sloping. This means that as the price of a good increases, the Hicksian quantity demanded will decrease, reflecting the pure substitution effect away from the now relatively more expensive good.