Skip to main content
← Back to I Definitions

Information cascade

What Is Information Cascade?

An information cascade occurs when individuals make decision-making based primarily on the observed actions of others, often disregarding or underweighting their own private information or signals. This phenomenon falls under the umbrella of behavioral economics and helps explain collective behaviors in various contexts, including financial markets. In an information cascade, early decisions create a strong public signal that subsequent individuals follow, even if their own insights suggest a different course of action. This leads to a convergence of actions, where the collective choice can become detached from underlying fundamental information.

History and Origin

The theory of information cascades was formally introduced and extensively explored in the early 1990s by economists Sushil Bikhchandani, David Hirshleifer, and Ivo Welch. Their foundational work, including a notable paper titled "A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change in Informational Cascades" (1992), provided a rigorous framework for understanding how seemingly rational individuals can contribute to widespread, sometimes erroneous, collective behavior by observing and imitating prior actions12. A subsequent paper, "Learning from the Behavior of Others: Conformity, Fads, and Informational Cascades," further elaborated on how social learning and observational learning can lead to such phenomena, explaining various puzzling aspects of human behavior such as fads and the fragility of mass actions11.

Key Takeaways

  • An information cascade describes sequential decision-making where individuals ignore their own private signals to follow the actions of those who came before them.
  • This behavior can arise even when individuals are rational, as it becomes optimal to rely on the aggregate public information suggested by earlier choices.
  • Information cascades can lead to large-scale, potentially erroneous, collective actions, such as market bubbles or crashes.
  • They are characterized by fragility, meaning a small piece of new, compelling information can potentially overturn the prevailing cascade.
  • The concept is distinct from pure imitation or mindless conformity, as it involves rational inferences based on observed actions and limited information10.

Interpreting the Information Cascade

An information cascade is not a numeric value or a formula to calculate; rather, it is a descriptive theory explaining a pattern of collective behavior. Its interpretation lies in understanding the conditions under which it forms and its potential implications. When observing a rapid convergence of actions within a group—whether in investment trends, technology adoption, or consumer choices—it is important to consider if an information cascade is at play.

The core interpretation revolves around the idea that individuals, even those with significant private information, may choose to disregard it if the actions of enough preceding individuals strongly contradict their own signal. This is due to the inference that the collective actions of others represent a more robust information set. Therefore, a key aspect of interpreting an information cascade involves recognizing when individuals are acting based on publicly revealed choices rather than their independent analysis or direct knowledge. This can lead to situations where widespread behavior is based on very little original information.

#9# Hypothetical Example

Consider a scenario involving investment decisions in a new, unproven technology stock, "TechGrow Inc." Sarah, an experienced analyst, receives a strong positive signal from her research suggesting TechGrow will perform well. However, she observes that the first two investors to publicly buy the stock (perhaps large institutional investors) placed very small orders, indicating some hesitation. Following them, a third investor also makes a small purchase.

At this point, a fourth investor, David, has his own mild positive private signal about TechGrow. However, observing the three preceding small purchases, he rationally infers that their collective, seemingly cautious, behavior implies a less enthusiastic outlook than his own signal suggests. Despite his positive private signal, David decides to make only a small investment, or even no investment, to align with the apparent consensus. A fifth investor then sees four cautious purchases and, regardless of their own stronger private signal, also acts cautiously. This sequential decision-making, where individuals' actions are driven by the observed actions of others rather than solely their own information, constitutes an information cascade. If many follow, the stock market may fail to fully incorporate all available private information.

Practical Applications

Information cascades manifest in numerous real-world scenarios, particularly within financial markets and broader economic contexts.

  • Financial Markets: They can contribute to the formation of market bubbles and subsequent crashes. For instance, during the lead-up to the 1929 stock market crash (often referred to as Black Tuesday), investors observed others continually investing and profiting, leading them to follow suit without independent analysis, contributing to unsustainable asset prices. This collective imitation ultimately exacerbated the severity of the market collapse.
  • 8 Venture Capital Funding: Investors might follow others into funding rounds for startups, even if their own due diligence is inconclusive, fearing they might miss out on a successful trend.
  • Product Adoption: Consumers may adopt a new product or technology simply because they observe many others doing so, assuming its popularity signals quality, even without personal assessment.
  • Regulatory Actions: Regulatory bodies or policymakers might be influenced by actions taken by peer institutions in other jurisdictions, leading to similar policy adoptions without fully evaluating local conditions.

The theory also extends beyond finance, explaining phenomena in politics, fashion, and even criminal behavior, highlighting its pervasive influence on collective human actions.

#7# Limitations and Criticisms

While providing valuable insights, the theory of information cascades has certain limitations and criticisms. One major critique is the assumption that individuals can only observe the actions of others, not their private information or the payoffs of their decisions. In many real-world settings, individuals may gain insight into the reasoning behind others' choices or observe the success or failure of prior actions, which can alter the cascade's trajectory or prevent it from forming.

Another point of contention is the fragility of information cascades. While early models suggest that cascades can be easily overturned by new, sufficiently strong public information, re6al-world cascades, particularly those driven by strong investor psychology or emotional factors, may be more resilient. The concept of rational choice underpinning the cascade model also faces scrutiny from behavioral finance experts who highlight the role of biases and heuristics in decision-making, which may lead to behavior that is not strictly optimal even with limited information. Some research explores "self-correcting information cascades," where the cascade adapts or reverses as new information, even if initially ignored, eventually becomes salient.

#5# Information Cascade vs. Herd Behavior

While often used interchangeably, "information cascade" and "herd behavior" are distinct concepts within behavioral economics. Herd behavior broadly refers to individuals in a group acting in the same way, often ignoring their own beliefs or information, and can be driven by a variety of factors, including social pressure, direct benefits, or a simple desire to conform. An information cascade is a specific type of herd behavior, characterized by a sequential decision-making process where individuals rationally (or boundedly rationally) infer information from the actions of those who moved before them, overriding their own private information.

T4he key difference lies in the underlying motivation: herd behavior can be mindless imitation, but an information cascade is a product of seemingly logical inference based on observed actions, even if that inference leads to an collectively suboptimal outcome. In an information cascade, individuals are not necessarily pressured but are drawing rational conclusions from the limited observable data (i.e., others' choices).

#3# FAQs

How does an information cascade begin?

An information cascade typically starts when individuals make decisions sequentially, and later individuals observe the choices of those who acted earlier. If a sufficient number of early individuals make the same choice, it creates a strong public signal that can lead subsequent individuals to follow, even if their private information suggests otherwise.

Can an information cascade be wrong?

Yes, an information cascade can lead to an incorrect outcome. Since individuals in a cascade are relying on the actions of others rather than fully utilizing their own private knowledge, a wrong initial set of decisions can lead to an entire sequence of individuals making the same incorrect choice. The collective outcome may not reflect the true state of information available across all individuals.

#2## Why are information cascades important in finance?
Information cascades are crucial in finance because they can explain sudden shifts in market sentiment, the rapid adoption or abandonment of certain investments, and the formation of market bubbles or crashes. Understanding information cascades helps to analyze collective investment decisions and anticipate potential market instabilities that arise from how information is aggregated and acted upon in financial markets.1