Skip to main content
← Back to I Definitions

Input output models

What Are Input-Output Models?

Input-output models are quantitative economic tools used to analyze the interdependencies between different sectors of an economy. As a core component of economic analysis, these models provide a detailed picture of how industries produce goods and services, and how those outputs are consumed either as intermediate inputs by other industries or by final consumers. Input-output models belong to the broader field of econometrics, offering a structured way to understand the flow of transactions within an economic system. They illustrate that the output of one industry often serves as an input for another, creating a complex web of economic relationships that drives overall Gross Domestic Product (GDP).

History and Origin

The foundation of modern input-output models is attributed to Wassily Leontief, a Russian-born American economist who developed this analytical framework in the 1930s and 1940s. Leontief, while a professor at Harvard, calculated an input-output table for the American economy in 1941, work for which he later received the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences in 1973.15,14 His pioneering efforts transformed abstract economic theory into a quantifiable method for understanding the intricate production processes and inter-industry flows within an economy.13 Leontief's work was partly inspired by earlier concepts of general equilibrium and inter-industry flows.12 The development of input-output analysis was driven by a desire to "collect facts" and understand the empirical realities of economic structures, rather than solely focusing on abstract theories.11

Key Takeaways

  • Input-output models map the interdependencies among industries, showing what each sector buys and sells.
  • They distinguish between intermediate goods used in production and goods or services purchased for final demand.
  • These models help quantify the direct and indirect impacts of changes in one economic sector on others.
  • Input-output analysis is widely used for economic forecasting, policy analysis, and understanding supply chain dynamics.
  • A key assumption of traditional input-output models is that production relationships (technical coefficients) remain fixed, which is a common area of criticism.

Formula and Calculation

The core of an input-output model is represented by a system of linear equations, often expressed in matrix form. The fundamental equation is the Leontief production function, which describes how the total output of each industry is distributed as intermediate inputs to other industries and as final demand.

The Leontief input-output equation is:

X=(IA)1FX = (I - A)^{-1}F

Where:

  • (X) = A column vector of total output for each industry.
  • (I) = The identity matrix.
  • (A) = The technical coefficients matrix (or input coefficient matrix), where each element (a_{ij}) represents the amount of input from industry (i) required to produce one unit of output in industry (j).
  • (F) = A column vector of final demand for the output of each industry.
  • ((I - A)^{-1}) = The Leontief inverse matrix, also known as the multiplier effect matrix, which shows the total (direct and indirect) output required from each industry for a one-unit change in final demand.

The elements of the (A) matrix, the technical coefficients, are calculated by dividing the value of intermediate inputs from industry (i) used by industry (j) by the total output of industry (j). This matrix is central to understanding the proportional requirements of inputs for a given output.

Interpreting the Input-Output Model

Interpreting an input-output model involves understanding the interconnectedness of an economy. The model's strength lies in its ability to trace direct and indirect economic impacts. For instance, if there is an increase in the final demand for automobiles, input-output models can estimate not only the direct increase in automobile manufacturing but also the indirect increase in demand for steel, rubber, glass, and other intermediate goods required by the automobile industry and its suppliers.

The Leontief inverse matrix, ((I - A)^{-1}), provides "multipliers" that illustrate the total output generated throughout the economy for each unit of final demand. A higher multiplier for a given industry indicates that changes in its final demand will have a larger ripple effect across other sectors, making it a critical part of industry analysis.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a simplified economy with two sectors: Agriculture and Manufacturing.

Assume the following technical coefficients matrix (A):

A=[0.20.10.30.4]A = \begin{bmatrix} 0.2 & 0.1 \\ 0.3 & 0.4 \end{bmatrix}

This means:

  • Agriculture needs 0.2 units of its own output and 0.3 units of Manufacturing output to produce 1 unit of Agriculture output.
  • Manufacturing needs 0.1 units of Agriculture output and 0.4 units of its own output to produce 1 unit of Manufacturing output.

Suppose the final demand vector (F) is:
Agriculture: 100 units
Manufacturing: 150 units

So, (F = \begin{bmatrix} 100 \ 150 \end{bmatrix})

First, calculate ((I - A)):

IA=[1001][0.20.10.30.4]=[0.80.10.30.6]I - A = \begin{bmatrix} 1 & 0 \\ 0 & 1 \end{bmatrix} - \begin{bmatrix} 0.2 & 0.1 \\ 0.3 & 0.4 \end{bmatrix} = \begin{bmatrix} 0.8 & -0.1 \\ -0.3 & 0.6 \end{bmatrix}

Next, calculate the inverse, ((I - A)^{-1}). For a 2x2 matrix (\begin{bmatrix} a & b \ c & d \end{bmatrix}), the inverse is (\frac{1}{ad-bc}\begin{bmatrix} d & -b \ -c & a \end{bmatrix}).

Determinant ( = (0.8 \times 0.6) - (-0.1 \times -0.3) = 0.48 - 0.03 = 0.45)

(IA)1=10.45[0.60.10.30.8][1.3330.2220.6671.778](I - A)^{-1} = \frac{1}{0.45} \begin{bmatrix} 0.6 & 0.1 \\ 0.3 & 0.8 \end{bmatrix} \approx \begin{bmatrix} 1.333 & 0.222 \\ 0.667 & 1.778 \end{bmatrix}

Finally, calculate total output (X = (I - A)^{-1}F):

X=[1.3330.2220.6671.778][100150]=[(1.333×100)+(0.222×150)(0.667×100)+(1.778×150)]=[133.3+33.366.7+266.7]=[166.6333.4]X = \begin{bmatrix} 1.333 & 0.222 \\ 0.667 & 1.778 \end{bmatrix} \begin{bmatrix} 100 \\ 150 \end{bmatrix} = \begin{bmatrix} (1.333 \times 100) + (0.222 \times 150) \\ (0.667 \times 100) + (1.778 \times 150) \end{bmatrix} = \begin{bmatrix} 133.3 + 33.3 \\ 66.7 + 266.7 \end{bmatrix} = \begin{bmatrix} 166.6 \\ 333.4 \end{bmatrix}

So, to meet the final demand of 100 units for Agriculture and 150 units for Manufacturing, the total output required from the Agriculture sector is approximately 166.6 units, and from the Manufacturing sector, approximately 333.4 units. This demonstrates how the model captures the ripple effects of production requirements.

Practical Applications

Input-output models have diverse practical applications across various sectors of the economy and public policy. They are extensively used by government agencies, international organizations, and businesses for economic forecasting and policy analysis.

The U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) regularly publishes detailed Input-Output Accounts, providing a comprehensive picture of the inner workings of the U.S. economy, including production relationships among industries and commodities.10 These accounts are vital for understanding supply chain dependencies and for analyzing the economic effects of specific events, such as changes in energy prices or shifts in consumer spending.9 Similarly, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) develops Inter-Country Input-Output (ICIO) tables to map global production, consumption, investment, and trade flows between countries.8 These international input-output tables are particularly relevant for analyzing global value chains and the impacts of trade policies or economic shocks.7 Businesses can leverage input-output data to develop market projections and understand their interdependencies within the broader economic landscape. For instance, the models can assess the impact of a major infrastructure project on various supporting industries, or the effects of a technological shift on specific commodity markets.

Limitations and Criticisms

While powerful, input-output models are subject to several limitations and criticisms. A primary critique revolves around the assumption of fixed technical coefficients. This assumption implies that industries use inputs in fixed proportions, regardless of changes in prices or technology.6,5 In reality, businesses often substitute inputs (e.g., capital for labor) in response to relative price changes or technological advancements, which the basic input-output model does not account for.4 Research suggests that taking coefficients as fixed can lead to misleading economic implications, as the elasticity of substitution between inputs is often greater than zero.3

Another limitation is the static nature of traditional input-output models, meaning they represent an economy at a specific point in time and do not inherently capture dynamic changes or technological progress. The models also simplify economic behavior by assuming linear relationships and do not explicitly incorporate optimizing behavior by producers or consumers.2 Furthermore, the construction of detailed input-output tables requires extensive data collection, which can be costly and time-consuming, and data availability can limit the model's granularity or timeliness.1

Input-Output Models vs. General Equilibrium Models

Input-output models are a specific type of general equilibrium models. Both frameworks aim to analyze the economy as a whole, considering the interactions between various markets and sectors. However, a key distinction lies in their assumptions and complexity.

Traditional input-output models operate under a fixed-coefficient assumption, meaning the proportion of inputs required for a unit of output is constant. They are particularly strong in detailing inter-industry linkages and quantifying the flow of intermediate goods and services. Their primary focus is on the supply-side relationships and the direct and indirect requirements for production.

General equilibrium models, particularly computable general equilibrium (CGE) models, are typically more complex and flexible. Unlike standard input-output models, CGE models allow for substitution between inputs in response to price changes, incorporate consumer behavior, and can analyze the impact of various policy changes on prices, wages, and resource allocation across the entire economy. While input-output models provide a detailed structural view, CGE models offer a more behavioral and market-driven perspective, often used for more comprehensive policy simulations that include market adjustments and resource reallocations.

FAQs

What is the primary purpose of an input-output model?

The primary purpose of an input-output model is to analyze the intricate interdependencies among industries within an economy, showing how the output of one industry becomes an input for others. It helps quantify the direct and indirect economic impacts of changes in final demand or supply.

Who uses input-output models?

Input-output models are used by government agencies for economic planning and policy evaluation, businesses for market analysis and strategic planning, and economists for academic research and economic forecasting. International organizations also use them to study global trade and supply chains.

What are technical coefficients in an input-output model?

Technical coefficients represent the amount of a specific input (from one industry) required to produce one unit of output in another industry. These coefficients form the "A" matrix in the input-output formula and are crucial for understanding the direct input requirements for production. They are derived from observed economic data, often from national income accounts.

Can input-output models predict future economic conditions?

While input-output models are valuable for economic forecasting, especially for short-term and structural analyses, their predictive power is limited by their static nature and the assumption of fixed technical coefficients. They are best used to understand the potential implications of specific changes given current economic structures rather than predicting unconstrained future outcomes.

How do input-output models relate to Gross Domestic Product (GDP)?

Input-output models can provide a detailed breakdown of the components that contribute to Gross Domestic Product. The sum of all final demands in an input-output model represents the total value of goods and services produced for final consumption, which is a key measure of GDP. Additionally, they can be used to calculate the value added by each industry.