Skip to main content
← Back to J Definitions

Jean baptiste say

What Is Jean-Baptiste Say?

Jean-Baptiste Say was a prominent French classical economist, often identified as a key figure in the development of economic theory during the late 18th and early 19th centuries. His work largely built upon and popularized the ideas of Adam Smith, yet he also introduced original concepts, most notably "Say's Law of Markets," which posits that supply creates its own demand. Say's contributions extend beyond this singular law, encompassing discussions on entrepreneurship, the nature of utility as the basis of value, and the role of production in generating wealth. His theories laid foundational groundwork for much of subsequent classical economics.

History and Origin

Born in Lyon, France, in 1767, Jean-Baptiste Say embarked on a diverse career that included working for an insurance company, serving as a journalist, and operating a cotton factory, before he became a leading political economist. His exposure to Adam Smith's The Wealth of Nations profoundly influenced his thinking, leading him to popularize Smith's free-market ideas in France. Say's most significant work, Traité d'économie politique (A Treatise on Political Economy), published in 1803, became a widely read textbook across Europe and the United States.

11The central concept associated with Jean-Baptiste Say is "Say's Law of Markets." This idea, though articulated by Say, was also rephrased by others, including James Mill, who is sometimes credited with the phrase "supply creates its own demand." S10ay’s Law emerged during a period of significant economic change, including the early Industrial Revolution, and offered a powerful perspective on how economies function and grow. His ideas were particularly influential in the context of the economic upheavals of his time, including the French Revolution and the Napoleonic era, during which he served on a government finance committee.

##9 Key Takeaways

  • Jean-Baptiste Say was a French classical economist best known for "Say's Law of Markets."
  • Say's Law suggests that the act of producing goods generates the necessary income to purchase other goods, implying that general overproduction or widespread lack of demand is unlikely in the long run.
  • He emphasized the critical role of the entrepreneur in economic activity, seeing them as organizers who combine productive agents like capital and labor.
  • Say advocated for free trade, competition, and reduced government intervention in the economy.
  • His work provided an early understanding that the value of a good stems from its utility to the consumer, diverging from the labor theory of value held by some contemporaries.

Formula and Calculation

Jean-Baptiste Say's key contributions are primarily theoretical and conceptual, rather than involving specific mathematical formulas or calculations. His ideas pertain to the relationships between production, consumption, and markets at a macroeconomic level, rather than quantifiable metrics. Therefore, a formula and calculation section is not applicable to the subject of Jean-Baptiste Say himself.

Interpreting the Jean-Baptiste Say

Interpreting Jean-Baptiste Say primarily involves understanding his central economic philosophy, particularly Say's Law. This law suggests that the aggregate supply of goods and services in an economy generates an equivalent amount of aggregate demand. Simply put, when producers create goods, they incur costs in the form of wages, rents, and profits, which then become the income available to consumers to purchase those goods or other goods.

Therefore, Say's perspective implies that a general "glut" or widespread oversupply across all markets is inherently self-correcting or temporary. If there is a surplus in one area, it suggests a corresponding deficiency elsewhere, which market forces will eventually resolve through price adjustments and resource reallocation. His framework suggests that economic growth is driven by the supply side, emphasizing the importance of production and the conditions that enable it.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a simplified economy with two individuals, Alice and Bob. Alice is a baker who produces bread, and Bob is a shoemaker who produces shoes. According to Jean-Baptiste Say's thinking, when Alice bakes bread, she incurs costs (for flour, yeast, her own labor) which become her income. With this income, she can then demand, or purchase, shoes from Bob. Similarly, when Bob makes shoes, his costs become his income, which he can then use to demand bread from Alice.

The act of producing bread (supply) directly creates the means for Alice to demand shoes, and the act of producing shoes creates the means for Bob to demand bread. There is no idle money or general lack of purchasing power, as long as production is occurring. If Alice bakes too much bread, the market signals this, and she might shift some of her resources to baking cakes, which Bob might demand more of, thus reallocating production to meet actual needs. This continuous cycle of production generating income, which then fuels consumption, is the essence of Say's Law in action.

Practical Applications

Jean-Baptiste Say's ideas, particularly Say's Law, continue to resonate in contemporary economic discussions, especially within supply-side economics. Proponents of supply-side policies often argue that stimulating production through measures like tax cuts, deregulation, and investment incentives will naturally lead to increased demand and overall economic growth. This perspective suggests that focusing on the conditions that enable businesses to produce more effectively is key to prosperity, rather than stimulating demand directly through government spending.

Historically, Say's Law provided a theoretical underpinning for the belief that free-market economies would naturally tend towards full employment and prosperity without significant government intervention. It implies that unemployment, if it occurs, is more likely due to structural factors or rigidities in the market, such as wages being artificially high, rather than a general deficiency of demand.

##8 Limitations and Criticisms

While influential, Say's Law has faced significant criticism, most notably from the British economist John Maynard Keynes during the Great Depression. Keynes argued that Say's Law, in its short-run interpretation that there could be no overproduction, was incorrect and that economies could indeed suffer from a persistent lack of aggregate demand, leading to high unemployment.

Keynes highlighted that individuals might choose to hoard money (save) rather than spend it, breaking the direct link between production and consumption. This "leakage" from the circular flow of income could lead to a situation where total demand falls short of total supply, resulting in economic stagnation. The7 experience of the Great Depression, with widespread unemployment and underutilized capacity, was seen by many as empirical evidence against the short-run applicability of Say's Law. Critics contend that while supply might create the capacity for demand, it does not guarantee the will to demand, especially during periods of economic uncertainty when individuals and businesses may prefer to save.

Jean-Baptiste Say vs. John Maynard Keynes

The economic thought of Jean-Baptiste Say and John Maynard Keynes represents a fundamental divide in macroeconomics, particularly concerning the role of demand in an economy.

FeatureJean-Baptiste Say's ViewJohn Maynard Keynes's View
Core PrincipleSay's Law: Supply creates its own demand. The act of production generates sufficient income to purchase all output.Keynes' Law: Demand creates its own supply (in the short run). A lack of effective demand can lead to underemployment and economic stagnation. 6
Economic EquilibriumAssumes the economy naturally tends towards full employment and optimal resource allocation, as markets self-correct. General gluts are impossible or momentary.Argues that an economy can reach equilibrium at less than full employment due to insufficient aggregate demand. Persistent unemployment is possible.
Role of SavingsSavings are seen as immediately channeled into investment; money is simply a medium of exchange, not held out of circulation.Savings can be a leakage from the circular flow of income if not matched by investment, leading to a shortfall in demand. Money can be hoarded.
Government PolicyAdvocates for minimal government intervention (laissez-faire), focusing on policies that encourage production and free markets.Recommends active government intervention (fiscal and monetary policy) to manage aggregate demand, especially during recessions, to achieve full employment. 5
ApplicabilityMore accurately describes long-run economic tendencies, where resources are reallocated over time to meet demands created by past production. 4More accurately describes short-run economic behavior, especially during economic downturns, where demand fluctuations directly impact production levels and employment. 3

While Say's Law emphasizes the fundamental link between production and purchasing power, Keynesian economics highlights the potential for a disconnect in that link due to factors like saving and expectations, particularly in the short run.

FAQs

What is Jean-Baptiste Say's most famous contribution to economics?

Jean-Baptiste Say is most famous for "Say's Law of Markets," often summarized as "supply creates its own demand." This concept posits that the act of producing goods and services inherently generates the income necessary to purchase them.

Did Jean-Baptiste Say believe in government intervention in the economy?

No, Jean-Baptiste Say was a strong advocate of classical liberal economic principles, favoring free markets, competition, and minimal government intervention. He believed that government policies should encourage production, not control it.

How does Say's Law relate to unemployment?

In Say's view, a general lack of aggregate demand leading to widespread unemployment is unlikely. Any unemployment would be temporary or due to specific market rigidities, not a fundamental inability of the economy to absorb its own production. His2 theory implies that a free-market economy naturally tends towards full employment.

What was Jean-Baptiste Say's view on value?

Jean-Baptiste Say was among the first economists to argue that the value of a good derives from its utility to the user, rather than solely from the labor expended in its production, as some of his contemporaries believed.

##1# How is Jean-Baptiste Say's work relevant today?
Say's emphasis on production as the engine of economic activity continues to influence supply-side economic theories and policies. His ideas remain a cornerstone for discussions about how wealth is created and distributed in an economy.