Skip to main content
← Back to L Definitions

Long run average cost

What Is Long-Run Average Cost?

Long-run average cost (LRAC) represents the per-unit cost of producing output when all inputs, including capital, are considered variable. Within the field of microeconomics, it provides a framework for firms to make strategic decisions about their scale of operations, as it reflects the lowest possible average total cost for producing each level of output when a company has sufficient time to adjust all of its factors of production. Unlike short-run cost analysis, where some inputs like plant size are fixed, the long-run perspective assumes that a firm can freely alter all inputs to achieve the most efficient production scale. This includes expanding or contracting facilities, acquiring new technology, or adjusting its workforce. The long-run average cost curve is a fundamental concept for understanding a firm's optimal production size and its competitive positioning within an industry. It is derived from a series of short-run average cost curves, each representing a different plant size or production capacity, and forms the envelope of these curves.

History and Origin

The foundational concepts of cost theory, including the distinction between short-run and long-run costs, emerged with the development of neoclassical economics. Early economists like Adam Smith and David Ricardo laid groundwork by discussing the "cost of production" as a determinant of value. However, it was the English economist Alfred Marshall who significantly advanced the understanding of cost curves and their role in determining market equilibrium in his seminal work, Principles of Economics, first published in 1890. Marshall introduced the idea that costs are determined by both the duration of the production period and the responsiveness of inputs. He emphasized that in the "long period," all factors of production are variable, allowing firms to adjust their scale to achieve the most efficient output levels. Marshall's framework, which also integrated supply and demand as "two blades of a pair of scissors" in price determination, formalized the relationship between a firm's output decisions and its costs over different time horizons.5

Key Takeaways

  • Long-run average cost (LRAC) is the per-unit cost of production when all inputs are variable.
  • The LRAC curve typically exhibits a U-shape, reflecting initial economies of scale followed by diseconomies of scale.
  • The lowest point on the LRAC curve represents the minimum efficient scale of production.
  • LRAC is a crucial tool for businesses making long-term strategic decisions regarding plant size and capacity.
  • It serves as a planning device, allowing firms to select the most cost-efficient production scale for various output levels.

Formula and Calculation

The formula for long-run average cost is straightforward: it is the total cost of production in the long run divided by the quantity of output produced.

LRAC=LRTCQLRAC = \frac{LRTC}{Q}

Where:

  • (LRAC) = Long-Run Average Cost
  • (LRTC) = Long-Run Total Cost, which represents the lowest possible total cost of producing a given output level when all inputs are variable.
  • (Q) = Quantity of output produced

Calculating LRAC involves first determining the optimal combination of factors of production for each possible level of output, assuming that all inputs, including capital, can be adjusted. This optimization is often guided by the firm's production function, which mathematically describes the relationship between inputs and output.

Interpreting the Long-Run Average Cost

The long-run average cost curve is typically U-shaped, illustrating the presence of economies of scale at lower output levels and diseconomies of scale at higher output levels. As a firm increases its production capacity and output, it initially experiences economies of scale, where the LRAC falls. This can be due to factors such as specialization of labor, more efficient use of machinery, bulk purchasing discounts, or improved organizational efficiencies.

However, beyond a certain point, the firm may encounter diseconomies of scale, causing the LRAC to rise. This increase in average cost can result from managerial inefficiencies, communication breakdowns in larger organizations, or increased bureaucracy. The lowest point on the LRAC curve is known as the minimum efficient scale, representing the optimal plant size or scale of operations where the firm can produce output at the lowest possible per-unit cost in the long run.4 Understanding the shape of the long-run average cost curve is critical for firms to make informed decisions about their optimal size and production strategy.

Hypothetical Example

Imagine "GreenTech Solar," a startup specializing in solar panel manufacturing. In its initial phase, GreenTech Solar operates a small plant (Capacity A) with basic machinery. Producing 1,000 panels per month, its average cost is high due to limited automation and higher per-unit costs for materials.

As demand for solar panels grows, GreenTech decides to expand. It invests in a larger, more automated factory (Capacity B), taking advantage of bulk discounts on raw materials and specialized labor. At this new scale, producing 5,000 panels per month, GreenTech experiences significant economies of scale. Its long-run average cost per panel falls considerably. The initial fixed costs of the larger plant are now spread over a much greater output, and the variable costs per unit are lower due to efficiency gains.

If GreenTech Solar were to grow even larger, building a massive global network of factories (Capacity C) to produce 50,000 panels per month, it might eventually encounter diseconomies of scale. Managing such a vast operation could lead to increased bureaucratic hurdles, communication inefficiencies, and difficulty in coordinating complex supply chains, causing its long-run average cost per panel to rise again. The LRAC curve, therefore, guides GreenTech in finding its optimal scale.

Practical Applications

Long-run average cost analysis has several practical applications in business and economics:

  • Strategic Planning and Investment: Businesses use LRAC to determine the most efficient scale of operation when planning for future growth or making significant capital investments. It helps them decide on the optimal plant size, production capacity, and the overall structure of their operations to achieve profit maximization.
  • Industry Analysis: Analysts use LRAC to understand the competitive landscape of an industry. Industries with significant economies of scale, where LRAC continues to fall over a wide range of output, tend to have fewer, larger firms (e.g., utilities, automotive manufacturing). This knowledge can inform decisions about market entry and exit.3
  • Pricing Decisions: While short-run costs influence day-to-day pricing, the long-run average cost helps inform long-term pricing strategies, especially for products with long production cycles or requiring substantial initial investment.
  • Policy and Regulation: Governments and regulatory bodies consider LRAC when evaluating industries, particularly those exhibiting characteristics of a natural monopoly. Understanding the cost structure can help in setting fair prices or regulating market behavior to protect consumers and ensure efficient resource allocation.
  • Assessment of Returns to Scale: The shape of the LRAC curve directly reflects the returns to scale a firm experiences. Decreasing LRAC indicates increasing returns to scale, constant LRAC indicates constant returns to scale, and increasing LRAC indicates decreasing returns to scale.

Limitations and Criticisms

While the long-run average cost curve is a powerful theoretical tool in microeconomics, it has certain limitations and criticisms when applied to the complexities of the real world:

  • Assumptions of Perfect Information and Flexibility: The theoretical LRAC assumes that a firm has complete knowledge of all possible production technologies and input prices, and can instantly adjust all its inputs without friction or cost. In reality, information is imperfect, and adjusting capital, labor, and technology can be costly and time-consuming.
  • Static vs. Dynamic Nature: The traditional LRAC curve is a static concept, depicting costs at a specific point in time given current technology. It often does not fully account for dynamic factors such as technological advancements, learning curve effects, or changes in management practices that can continuously shift the actual cost curves over time. Modern cost theories attempt to incorporate these dynamic elements.2
  • Difficulty in Measurement: Empirically measuring a true LRAC is challenging because firms are constantly operating within specific short-run capacities, and observed costs are a blend of short-run adjustments and long-run strategic decisions.
  • Relevance for All Industries: While the U-shaped curve is a common theoretical representation, the actual shape of average cost curves can vary significantly across industries. Some industries, like certain software companies, may experience near-constant or even continuously falling average costs due to very low marginal cost and substantial economies of scale even at very high output levels, making the traditional U-shape less pronounced or even absent.1

Long-Run Average Cost vs. Short-Run Average Cost

The key distinction between long-run average cost and short-run average cost lies in the flexibility of inputs available to a firm.

| Feature | Short-Run Average Cost (SRAC) | Long-Run Average Cost (LRAC)