Skip to main content
← Back to L Definitions

Long run concept

The long run concept is a fundamental principle within economic theory and microeconomics that refers to a theoretical period where all factors of production are variable. Unlike the short run, where at least one factor of production is fixed, the long run allows firms and industries sufficient time to adjust all inputs, including capital, labor, and technology, in response to changes in economic conditions. This flexibility means there are no fixed costs in the long run; all costs are variable costs. The long run concept is crucial for understanding how markets achieve market equilibrium over time.

History and Origin

The differentiation between "long run" and "short run" in economic models gained prominence with Alfred Marshall's seminal work, Principles of Economics, published in 1890. Marshall, a key figure in neoclassical economics, introduced the idea of different "time horizons" to analyze how markets adjust. He distinguished between the market period (where supply is fixed), the short period (where some factors are variable but capital is fixed), and the long period (where all factors are variable). This conceptual framework allowed economists to better understand how supply and demand interact over varying timeframes. Marshall's approach built upon earlier classical political economists who used a "long-period method" to examine production, distribution, and accumulation in a market economy.15, 16, 17

Key Takeaways

  • The long run concept in economics is a theoretical period where all factors of production are variable.
  • In the long run, firms can adjust plant size, enter new industries, or exit existing ones.
  • There are no fixed costs in the long run, only variable costs.
  • This concept is essential for analyzing long-term economic behavior, planning, and policy.
  • It allows for the full adjustment to profit maximization and efficient resource allocation.

Interpreting the Long run concept

The long run concept provides a framework for understanding how economic agents make decisions when they have complete flexibility to alter all their inputs. In this theoretical period, firms can modify their production capacity, adopt new technologies, or even change the scale of their operations. For instance, a firm operating in a state of perfect competition in the long run can achieve zero economic profit as new firms are free to enter the market, driving down prices until they equal average total costs. Conversely, a monopoly might adjust its production function to exploit economies of scale or contend with diseconomies of scale over this extended timeframe. The long run concept is purely theoretical; it does not correspond to a specific chronological duration.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a hypothetical scenario involving a small artisanal bread bakery. In the short run, if demand for their bread suddenly surges, the bakery might only be able to increase production by having existing staff work overtime or by adding a few more shifts. Their oven capacity and physical space are fixed. In the long run, however, the bakery has the flexibility to respond more fully to sustained high demand. This might involve expanding its current facility, purchasing larger or additional ovens, or even opening a second location in another part of the city. Over this extended period, the bakery can acquire new capital assets, hire and train more bakers, and completely restructure its operations to meet the new scale of demand. This full adjustment capacity defines the long run concept for the business.

Practical Applications

The long run concept has significant practical applications across various areas of finance and economics. Central banks, for example, often refer to "longer-run goals" in their monetary policy statements, aiming for stable prices and maximum employment over an extended period, recognizing that policy effects can have a lag.13, 14 In financial planning, the long run concept underpins strategies like long-term investment, where investors allocate capital with the expectation that market fluctuations will average out over many years, focusing on compound growth rather than short-term gains.12 Similarly, governments and international organizations, such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), publish long-term economic outlooks and projections for global growth, which rely on the premise of economies adjusting and evolving over time.8, 9, 10, 11

Limitations and Criticisms

While the long run concept is a powerful analytical tool, it faces several limitations and criticisms. One significant critique is its purely theoretical nature; the real world is constantly changing, meaning a true "long run" equilibrium, where all adjustments are complete, may never actually be reached. As John Maynard Keynes famously quipped, "In the long run, we are all dead," emphasizing the importance of short-term policy interventions over waiting for natural market corrections.7 Furthermore, some economists argue that general equilibrium models, which often underpin long-run analyses, can be overly complex and struggle to capture the full dynamics of real-world economies.4, 5, 6 Critics also point out that these models may not always accurately predict outcomes or account for factors like continuous technological progress or unforeseen market disruptions.1, 2, 3 The assumption of perfect flexibility and information in the long run can also be unrealistic, as real markets often operate with imbalances and rigidities.

Long run concept vs. Short run concept

The fundamental distinction between the long run concept and the short run concept lies in the flexibility of inputs. In the short run, at least one factor of production is fixed, typically capital or plant size. This means firms can only vary output by adjusting inputs like labor or raw materials. For instance, a factory cannot instantly build a new production line or shut down an old one in the short run. Consequently, short-run analysis often involves considering fixed costs and variable costs. In contrast, the long run concept assumes all factors of production are variable, allowing for complete adjustment of scale and the entry or exit of firms from an industry. This means all costs are variable in the long run. The short run focuses on immediate responses and constraints, while the long run provides a framework for analyzing ultimate equilibrium states and strategic changes over time, without a precise chronological definition.

FAQs

What is the primary characteristic of the long run concept in economics?

The primary characteristic of the long run concept is that all factors of production are variable, meaning firms have enough time to adjust all inputs, including capital, to optimize their operations.

Is the long run a specific period of time?

No, the long run is a theoretical concept and does not refer to a specific chronological duration. Its length varies by industry and depends on the time required for all adjustments to fixed factors to occur.

Why is the long run concept important in economics?

The long run concept is crucial for understanding how markets and firms achieve efficiency and equilibrium over time. It allows for the analysis of strategic decisions, industry structure, and the full impact of changes in technology or policy when all constraints have been overcome. It also helps in understanding concepts like opportunity cost over a longer horizon.

Are there any fixed costs in the long run?

No, by definition, there are no fixed costs in the long run. All costs are considered variable costs because a firm has sufficient time to adjust or dispose of all its inputs.

AI Financial Advisor

Get personalized investment advice

  • AI-powered portfolio analysis
  • Smart rebalancing recommendations
  • Risk assessment & management
  • Tax-efficient strategies

Used by 30,000+ investors