Skip to main content
← Back to M Definitions

Market inelasticity

_LINK_POOL:

What Is Market Inelasticity?

Market inelasticity describes a situation within economics where the quantity demanded or supplied of a good or service changes very little in response to a significant change in its price. This concept is fundamental to microeconomics, as it provides insight into the responsiveness of demand and supply in a given market. When a market exhibits inelasticity, it means that consumers or producers are relatively unresponsive to price fluctuations. Products considered necessities, for instance, often demonstrate market inelasticity because consumers will continue to purchase them regardless of price increases29.

History and Origin

The concept of elasticity, which underpins market inelasticity, was notably formalized by the English economist Alfred Marshall in his seminal 1890 work, Principles of Economics. Marshall is widely credited with defining "elasticity of demand," articulating how the responsiveness of demand varies with price changes27, 28. While earlier economists understood the general relationship between price and quantity, Marshall provided the precise vocabulary and mathematical framework that allowed for the quantification of this sensitivity25, 26. His work laid the groundwork for understanding how changes in price affect economic decisions for both consumers and producers, making elasticity a crucial tool in economic analysis24.

Key Takeaways

  • Market inelasticity refers to a minimal change in quantity demanded or supplied despite a significant price change.
  • It is often observed in markets for necessity goods or goods with few substitutes.
  • Understanding market inelasticity is crucial for businesses in setting pricing strategy and for governments in formulating tax policies.
  • The concept helps predict how revenue might be affected by price adjustments in different market conditions.

Formula and Calculation

Market inelasticity is typically measured using the Price Elasticity of Demand (PED) or Price Elasticity of Supply (PES). For demand, the formula calculates the responsiveness of the quantity demanded to a price change:

PED=%ΔQuantity Demanded%ΔPrice\text{PED} = \frac{\% \Delta \text{Quantity Demanded}}{\% \Delta \text{Price}}

Where:

  • (% \Delta \text{Quantity Demanded}) represents the percentage change in the quantity of a good or service consumers are willing and able to buy.
  • (% \Delta \text{Price}) represents the percentage change in the price of that good or service.

If the absolute value of the PED is less than 1, the demand is considered inelastic. This indicates that the percentage change in quantity demanded is proportionately less than the percentage change in price23. Similarly, Price Elasticity of Supply measures the responsiveness of quantity supplied to a price change.

Interpreting Market Inelasticity

When a market displays inelasticity, it implies that consumers' purchasing habits or producers' output levels are not highly sensitive to price movements. A low absolute value for the Price Elasticity of Demand (e.g., between 0 and -1) signifies that even a substantial price increase will only lead to a small decrease in the quantity demanded. This often occurs for essential items where consumers prioritize the product due to its high utility or lack of viable alternatives21, 22. For example, the demand for life-saving medications tends to be highly inelastic; people will generally pay what is necessary to obtain them, regardless of cost19, 20. Understanding this behavior is vital for businesses in assessing potential revenue outcomes from price adjustments.

Hypothetical Example

Consider the market for tap water in a residential area. Assume the local utility company decides to increase the price of water by 10%. Before the price change, residents consumed 1,000,000 gallons per month. After the price increase, consumption drops slightly to 995,000 gallons per month.

To calculate the Price Elasticity of Demand:

Percentage change in quantity demanded = (\frac{995,000 - 1,000,000}{1,000,000} \times 100% = -0.5%)
Percentage change in price = (10%)

PED = (\frac{-0.5%}{10%} = -0.05)

Since the absolute value of the PED (0.05) is much less than 1, the demand for tap water in this hypothetical scenario is highly inelastic. This demonstrates that even with a price hike, the quantity consumed saw only a negligible decrease, reflecting the essential nature of water as a necessity good.

Practical Applications

Market inelasticity has significant practical applications across various economic sectors. In business, it informs pricing strategy. Companies selling products with inelastic demand, such as certain pharmaceutical drugs or essential utilities, have greater flexibility to raise prices without experiencing a drastic drop in sales volume17, 18. This is because consumers have limited alternatives or the product is considered indispensable.

For governments, understanding market inelasticity is crucial for fiscal policy, particularly regarding taxation. Governments often impose taxes on goods with inelastic demand, like gasoline, tobacco, or alcohol, because such taxes generate substantial and predictable revenue with minimal impact on consumption patterns15, 16. The ability of the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) to influence global oil prices, for instance, relies partly on the relatively inelastic global demand for crude oil in the short term, despite market fluctuations and production targets12, 13, 14. This allows OPEC's actions to significantly impact international oil prices due to their considerable market share11.

Limitations and Criticisms

While market inelasticity is a powerful concept in economic analysis, it is not without limitations or criticisms. One primary critique is that elasticity values are not static; they can change over time and vary across different points on a demand or supply curve10. A product that exhibits inelastic demand in the short term might become more elastic in the long term as consumers discover or develop substitutes. For example, while gasoline demand might be inelastic immediately following a price increase, over several years, consumers might shift to more fuel-efficient vehicles or alternative transportation.

Furthermore, estimating true elasticity values in complex, real-world markets can be challenging due to numerous confounding variables influencing consumer behavior9. External factors like economic conditions, technological advancements, and even marketing efforts can all affect how responsive demand or supply is to price changes8. Relying solely on a historical elasticity measure without considering these dynamic influences can lead to inaccurate predictions and suboptimal policy decisions.

Market Inelasticity vs. Elasticity

Market inelasticity and elasticity describe opposite ends of a spectrum measuring responsiveness in economic variables.

FeatureMarket InelasticityMarket Elasticity
ResponsivenessLow; quantity demanded/supplied changes little.High; quantity demanded/supplied changes significantly.
Price ChangeLarge price changes lead to small quantity changes.Small price changes lead to large quantity changes.
Product TypeOften necessity goods or unique items.Often luxury goods or items with many substitutes.
PED/PES ValueAbsolute value is less than 1.Absolute value is greater than 1.

The key distinction lies in the degree to which quantity responds to price. When a good exhibits market inelasticity, its demand or supply curve is relatively steep, indicating that consumers or producers are largely committed regardless of price fluctuations. Conversely, an elastic market features a flatter curve, meaning even minor price adjustments can cause significant shifts in quantity. This distinction is crucial for understanding market equilibrium and predicting market reactions to policy changes or external shocks.

FAQs

What causes market inelasticity?

Market inelasticity is typically caused by factors such as the essential nature of a good (e.g., basic food, medication), a lack of readily available substitutes, or a very short time horizon where consumers or producers have little time to adjust their behavior6, 7. For example, in the short term, the demand for gasoline is relatively inelastic because people need to commute or transport goods, and immediate alternatives are limited.

How does government intervention relate to inelasticity?

Government intervention often targets goods with inelastic demand. Since demand for these goods remains stable despite price changes, governments can impose taxes (like excise taxes) to generate revenue without significantly reducing consumption, as seen with tobacco or alcohol3, 4, 5. Additionally, governments may regulate prices for essential inelastic goods, such as utilities or life-saving drugs, to prevent exploitation by companies with monopoly power and address potential market failure2.

Is market inelasticity always about demand?

No, market inelasticity can also apply to supply. Price Elasticity of Supply (PES) measures how much the quantity supplied of a good responds to a change in its price1. If supply is inelastic, producers find it difficult to quickly adjust their output in response to price changes, perhaps due to high production costs, limited raw materials, or long production cycles.