Skip to main content
← Back to M Definitions

Monetary aggregates

What Is Monetary Aggregates?

Monetary aggregates are official measures of the total amount of money circulating within an economy. These measures are fundamental to macroeconomics, providing central banks and economists with key insights into the money supply, which is crucial for formulating and implementing effective monetary policy. By classifying various forms of financial assets based on their liquidity, monetary aggregates help to gauge the health and direction of an economy. Central banks, like the Federal Reserve in the United States and the European Central Bank (ECB), routinely track these aggregates to understand economic activity, inflationary pressures, and the overall financial stability.

History and Origin

The concept of measuring the money supply dates back centuries, evolving as financial systems became more complex. In the United States, systematic efforts to quantify monetary aggregates gained traction in the early to mid-20th century. In 1944, the Federal Reserve System's Board of Governors began reporting monthly data on currency outside banks and demand deposits, which later became known as M1.15 This marked a formal recognition of the importance of these measures for public information on the nation's money supply.14

A pivotal moment in the study of monetary aggregates came with the 1963 publication of "A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960" by Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz. Their work argued that changes in the money supply profoundly influenced economic fluctuations, including exacerbating the Great Depression due to the Federal Reserve's failure to stabilize the money supply. This influential book highlighted the need for central banks to closely monitor and manage money. Over the decades, as new financial instruments and practices emerged, central banks redefined and expanded their monetary aggregates to better capture the evolving landscape of money, with major redefinitions occurring in the 1980s and 2020.,
13
12## Key Takeaways

  • Monetary aggregates categorize and measure the total money supply in an economy based on liquidity.
  • Central banks use these measures as vital economic indicators for guiding monetary policy decisions.
  • The primary aggregates, M1 and M2 (and historically M0 and M3), represent increasingly broader definitions of money.
  • Changes in monetary aggregates can signal potential shifts in inflation, economic growth, and interest rates.
  • Their usefulness as direct policy targets has been debated due to evolving financial markets and changes in their relationship with economic variables.

Formula and Calculation

Monetary aggregates are calculated by summing various financial assets, categorized primarily by their liquidity, or how easily they can be converted into cash. While the exact definitions can vary by country and central bank, common aggregates include:

  • M0 (Monetary Base): This is the narrowest measure, typically including currency in circulation (banknotes and coins) and commercial banks' reserves held at the central bank. It represents the money over which central banks have the most direct control. M0=Currency in Circulation+Bank ReservesM0 = \text{Currency in Circulation} + \text{Bank Reserves}
  • M1 (Narrow Money): This includes the most liquid forms of money that are readily available for transactions. In the United States, M1 comprises currency in circulation and demand deposits (e.g., checking accounts) at financial institutions, and other liquid deposits.,
    11 10 $$
    M1 = \text{Currency in Circulation} + \text{Demand Deposits} + \text{Other Liquid Deposits}
  • M2 (Intermediate Money): This is a broader measure that includes M1 plus less liquid forms of money that can still be easily converted into cash. In the U.S., M2 includes M1, plus small-denomination time deposits (less than $100,000) and balances in retail money market funds.
    9 $$
    M2 = M1 + \text{Small-Denomination Time Deposits} + \text{Retail Money Market Funds Balances}
  • M3 (Broad Money): Historically, M3 was an even broader measure, including M2 plus larger, less liquid assets like large-denomination time deposits, institutional money market funds, and repurchase agreements. Many central banks, including the Federal Reserve, have discontinued regular publication of M3 due to its limited usefulness as an economic indicator, though the European Central Bank still defines and monitors M3.,
    8
    7## Interpreting Monetary Aggregates

Interpreting monetary aggregates involves analyzing their growth rates and composition to infer potential economic trends. Rapid growth in monetary aggregates can sometimes signal rising inflationary pressures, as more money chasing a similar amount of goods and services could lead to higher prices. Conversely, slow or contracting growth might indicate a slowing economy or deflationary risks.

Policymakers and economists often look at changes in M1 and M2 in relation to other economic indicators such as Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and interest rates. For example, if M2 is growing faster than nominal GDP, it might suggest an excess of liquidity in the system, potentially leading to future inflation. However, the relationship between monetary aggregates and key economic variables can be complex and has varied over time, making interpretation challenging.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a simplified economy with the following monetary components at the beginning of the year:

  • Currency in circulation: $500 billion
  • Demand deposits: $1,500 billion
  • Small-denomination time deposits: $800 billion
  • Retail money market funds: $400 billion

Based on these figures, the monetary aggregates would be:

  1. Calculate M1:

    • M1 = Currency in circulation + Demand deposits
    • M1 = $500 billion + $1,500 billion = $2,000 billion
  2. Calculate M2:

    • M2 = M1 + Small-denomination time deposits + Retail money market funds
    • M2 = $2,000 billion + $800 billion + $400 billion = $3,200 billion

Now, imagine that by the end of the year, due to increased spending and bank lending, currency in circulation rises to $550 billion, demand deposits increase to $1,650 billion, and small-denomination time deposits grow to $850 billion, while retail money market funds remain at $400 billion.

The new aggregates would be:

  1. New M1:

    • New M1 = $550 billion + $1,650 billion = $2,200 billion
  2. New M2:

    • New M2 = $2,200 billion + $850 billion + $400 billion = $3,450 billion

In this hypothetical scenario, M1 grew by $200 billion ($2,200b - $2,000b), representing a 10% increase. M2 grew by $250 billion ($3,450b - $3,200b), approximately a 7.8% increase. Such growth in monetary aggregates would prompt economists and central banks to analyze whether this expansion aligns with economic growth targets or if it poses risks like higher inflation.

Practical Applications

Monetary aggregates are widely used by central banks, financial analysts, and economists in several practical applications:

  • Monetary Policy Formulation: Central banks, such as the Federal Reserve, monitor monetary aggregates as part of their broader assessment of economic conditions when setting interest rates and implementing quantitative easing or tightening. While direct targeting of aggregates is less common today, their movements provide valuable information about liquidity conditions and potential inflationary or deflationary pressures. For example, the Federal Reserve provides detailed weekly and monthly data on its H.6 Money Stock Measures release.
    *6 Economic Forecasting: Analysts use trends in monetary aggregates to forecast future economic activity, including consumption, investment, and Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Although the relationship has weakened over time, significant shifts in the money supply can still offer clues about the economy's momentum.
  • Academic Research: Monetary aggregates are essential data for economic research, particularly in the fields of macroeconomics and financial economics, where they are used to study money demand, the transmission mechanisms of monetary policy, and long-term economic growth.
  • Financial Stability Analysis: Tracking the components of monetary aggregates helps regulators understand the composition of the public's financial assets and liabilities, contributing to assessments of overall financial stability. Unusual shifts between different types of deposits or increases in repurchase agreements might signal stress in certain financial institutions or markets.

Limitations and Criticisms

Despite their historical importance, monetary aggregates face several limitations and criticisms, diminishing their role as precise guides for monetary policy:

  • Unstable Relationship with Economic Variables: A significant criticism is the increasingly unstable relationship between monetary aggregates and key economic outcomes like inflation and Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Financial innovation, such as the introduction of new types of bank accounts and payment methods, has blurred the lines between different forms of money and made their behavior less predictable. This has led many central banks to de-emphasize strict monetary targeting.
  • The Barnett Critique: Economist William A. Barnett and others have argued that traditional "simple-sum" monetary aggregates, which treat all components (like currency and various deposits) as perfect substitutes, are theoretically inconsistent. T5hey contend that these aggregates do not accurately capture the varying "moneyness" or liquidity services provided by different assets, especially when interest rates on these components change. This "Barnett critique" suggests that more sophisticated "Divisia" monetary aggregates, which weight assets by their user cost (opportunity cost of holding them), might offer a more stable relationship with economic variables.,
    4*3 Difficulty in Control: Central banks have less direct control over the broader aggregates (M2, M3) compared to the monetary base (M0), making them less reliable as operational targets. Decisions by households and financial institutions on how to hold their money (e.g., shifting between checking accounts and savings accounts) can significantly impact the aggregates without reflecting a direct policy action.
  • Globalization: In an interconnected global economy, domestic monetary aggregates might not fully capture the influence of cross-border financial flows and the availability of foreign currencies, complicating their interpretation.

These factors have led many central banks to adopt more eclectic approaches to monetary policy, relying on a wider range of economic indicators beyond just monetary aggregates.

Monetary Aggregates vs. Money Supply

While the terms "monetary aggregates" and "money supply" are often used interchangeably in general discussion, in a precise financial context, monetary aggregates are the specific, categorized measurements of the broader concept of money supply. The money supply refers to the total amount of currency and other liquid assets in a country's economy at a particular time. It encompasses all the readily spendable funds held by the public.

Monetary aggregates, on the other hand, are the defined classifications or measures of that money supply. They represent different levels of liquidity within the money supply, such as M1, M2, and M3. M1 is considered the narrowest definition of the money supply, including only the most liquid components. M2 is a broader aggregate, encompassing M1 plus less liquid but still accessible forms of money. Therefore, while "money supply" is the overarching concept of available money, "monetary aggregates" are the actual tools and categories used by central banks to quantify and analyze that supply. The confusion often arises because each aggregate is a measure of the money supply, just a different one based on what is included.

FAQs

Q1: Why do central banks track monetary aggregates?
A1: Central banks track monetary aggregates to gain insights into the economy's liquidity, potential inflationary pressures, and overall economic activity. This information helps them make informed decisions regarding interest rates and other monetary policy tools aimed at maintaining price stability and supporting economic growth.

Q2: What is the most important monetary aggregate?
A2: There isn't one universally "most important" monetary aggregate, as their relevance can change over time. Historically, M1 and M2 have been widely observed. For central banks like the European Central Bank, M3 is also closely monitored as a key reference for monetary policy. The usefulness of each aggregate depends on the specific economic context and the stability of its relationship with other economic variables.

Q3: How do monetary aggregates affect my investments?
A3: Monetary aggregates indirectly affect investments by influencing central bank monetary policy. For instance, if monetary aggregates grow rapidly, central banks might consider raising interest rates to curb inflation, which can impact bond yields, stock valuations, and currency exchange rates. Investors often monitor these trends as part of their macroeconomic analysis.

Q4: Are monetary aggregates the same in every country?
A4: No, the exact definitions and components of monetary aggregates can vary from country to country, reflecting differences in their financial systems and banking practices. While there are common categories like M1 and M2, the specific assets included within each aggregate may differ. International organizations like the International Monetary Fund (IMF) provide harmonized data to facilitate cross-country comparisons.,[21](https://fred.stlouisfed.org/tags/series?t=imf%3Bmonetary+aggregates)