Skip to main content
← Back to N Definitions

New classical macroeconomics

What Is New Classical Macroeconomics?

New classical macroeconomics is a school of economic thought within the broader field of macroeconomics that emerged in the 1970s, emphasizing the importance of individual optimizing behavior and rational expectations in determining aggregate economic outcomes. It posits that economic agents, such as households and firms, make decisions by optimally using all available information, leading to efficient markets and the rapid adjustment of prices and wages. This contrasts with earlier macroeconomic schools that often assumed "sticky" prices or irrational behavior. A core tenet of new classical macroeconomics is that systematic government interventions, particularly in monetary policy and fiscal policy, are ineffective in altering real economic variables like output and employment in the long run, as agents will anticipate and neutralize their effects.

History and Origin

The new classical macroeconomics school originated in the early 1970s, primarily through the work of economists at the Universities of Chicago and Minnesota, including Robert Lucas, Thomas Sargent, Neil Wallace, and Edward Prescott. Its development can be seen as a reaction against the then-dominant Keynesian economics, which struggled to explain the stagflation of the 1970s—a period of high inflation and high unemployment. The new classical economists sought to provide microfoundations for macroeconomic phenomena, building on the idea that macroeconomic patterns are the result of individuals' optimizing choices.,
11
10A pivotal concept introduced by Lucas was the "Lucas critique," which argued that traditional econometric models used for policy evaluation were flawed because their parameters, derived from historical data, would change when the underlying policy rules changed. This implied that policymakers could not reliably predict the effects of new policies based on past observations. For instance, the historically observed negative correlation between inflation and unemployment, known as the Phillips curve, was challenged, with new classical economists arguing that attempts to exploit it through persistent inflationary policies would ultimately lead to higher inflation without a permanent reduction in unemployment.

Key Takeaways

  • New classical macroeconomics posits that economic agents have rational expectations and optimize their decisions based on all available information.
  • It argues that markets clear quickly, and prices and wages are flexible, leading the economy to remain at or near its potential output.
  • Systematic monetary and fiscal policies are considered ineffective in influencing real economic variables in the long run due to agents' ability to anticipate and react to these policies.
  • The school emphasizes the importance of supply-side factors and robust individual decision-making in determining macroeconomic outcomes.
  • A significant contribution is the Lucas critique, highlighting that economic models' parameters are not invariant to policy changes.

Formula and Calculation

New classical macroeconomics does not typically involve a single, overarching formula in the way, for example, a financial ratio might. Instead, it relies heavily on dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models, which are complex mathematical frameworks representing the entire economy. These models are built from the ground up, starting with the optimizing behavior of individual agents.

A simplified representation of how rational expectations might affect a general economic variable, (X_t), can be expressed:

Xt=Et[Xt+1]+ϵtX_t = E_t[X_{t+1}] + \epsilon_t

Where:

  • (X_t) represents the current value of an economic variable (e.g., output, inflation).
  • (E_t[X_{t+1}]) represents the expectation of the variable (X) in the next period ((t+1)), formed at time (t), using all available information.
  • (\epsilon_t) represents an unanticipated shock or error term, reflecting unexpected events.

This highlights that current values are heavily influenced by forward-looking expectations about the future, rather than solely by past data. Economic agents are assumed to use all relevant information, including information about government policies, to form these expectations. The models often incorporate elements like utility maximization for households and profit maximization for firms, which are solved mathematically to determine economic equilibrium conditions.

Interpreting the New Classical Macroeconomics

New classical macroeconomics suggests that observable economic fluctuations, or the business cycle, are primarily driven by unanticipated shocks to aggregate supply or aggregate demand, rather than by systematic government policy. Because agents are rational and markets adjust quickly, the economy is always striving toward its natural rate of output and unemployment.

From this perspective, policymakers should avoid "fine-tuning" the economy, as their systematic actions will be anticipated by rational agents and will only lead to changes in nominal variables (like the price level) without affecting real output or employment. For instance, an announced increase in the money supply, if fully anticipated, will lead to an immediate proportional increase in prices and wages, leaving real economic activity unchanged. The implication is that policy should focus on creating a stable and predictable environment rather than attempting to manipulate short-run outcomes.

9## Hypothetical Example
Consider a hypothetical economy where the central bank announces its intention to significantly increase the money supply to stimulate job growth. According to the tenets of new classical macroeconomics, rational agents in this economy would anticipate the inflationary effects of this monetary policy.

Scenario:

  1. Central Bank Announcement: The central bank declares a plan to expand the money supply by 10% next quarter, aiming to reduce unemployment.
  2. Rational Expectations: Businesses and workers, acting with rational expectations, immediately foresee that this increase in the money supply will lead to a 10% rise in the general price level.
  3. Wage and Price Adjustments: Workers will instantly demand 10% higher nominal wages to maintain their real purchasing power, and businesses will raise their prices by 10% to protect their profit margins.
  4. No Real Impact: As nominal wages and prices adjust simultaneously and proportionally, there is no change in relative prices or real wages. Businesses face higher labor costs but also receive higher prices for their goods. Workers earn more but face higher costs of living. Consequently, there is no real incentive for firms to hire more workers, and no change in aggregate output or employment. The intended stimulus from the expansionary policy is neutralized by agents' forward-looking behavior.

This example illustrates the concept of policy ineffectiveness under new classical assumptions, where only unexpected policy changes can have a temporary real impact.

Practical Applications

While new classical macroeconomics largely argues against systematic active stabilization policies, its core ideas have profoundly influenced economic analysis and policy discourse. The emphasis on rational expectations has become a standard assumption in many modern macroeconomic models, including those used by central banks.

  • Monetary Policy Formulation: Central banks now pay close attention to managing expectations of inflation, acknowledging that how the public anticipates future policy actions can significantly influence current economic outcomes. For example, some argue for predictable and stable growth in the money supply to minimize uncertainty.
    *8 Critique of Discretionary Policy: The school provides a theoretical basis for skepticism regarding discretionary fiscal policy and monetary policy aimed at short-run stabilization. It suggests that such attempts often lead to unintended consequences or simply result in changes in nominal variables, without affecting real output or employment.
    *7 Structural Reforms: The focus on supply-side economics and market clearing mechanisms implies that policies fostering greater market flexibility and reducing rigidities are more effective in promoting long-term economic growth than demand-management policies.
  • Debt and Taxation: New classical economists, particularly when considering phenomena like Ricardian equivalence, argue that government debt financed by current borrowing implies future taxation. Rational agents might anticipate this future tax burden and adjust their saving behavior accordingly, potentially nullifying the stimulative effects of debt-financed spending.

6## Limitations and Criticisms
Despite its significant influence, new classical macroeconomics faces several limitations and criticisms:

  • Assumption of Rational Expectations: A major critique centers on the assumption that individuals possess perfect information and the cognitive ability to form truly rational expectations. Critics argue that in the real world, information is imperfect, and individuals often rely on adaptive expectations or "rules of thumb" rather than fully internalizing complex economic models.,
    5*4 Market Clearing and Price Flexibility: The rapid and complete market clearing implied by new classical models is often challenged by empirical evidence of "sticky" prices and wages, which can lead to involuntary unemployment and persistent deviations from full employment in the short run.
  • The Lucas Critique's Empirical Relevance: While theoretically profound, some studies have questioned the practical empirical significance of the Lucas critique, suggesting that observed policy shifts have not always led to the predicted instability in econometric model parameters.,
    3*2 Relevance for Recessions: Critics, notably New Keynesian economists, argue that new classical models struggle to explain prolonged recessions and high unemployment, as they tend to view such phenomena as short-lived adjustments to unexpected shocks. N1obel laureate Paul Krugman, for instance, has often highlighted the real-world implications of "sticky" prices and the need for active policy intervention during economic downturns, contrasting with the new classical emphasis on market self-correction.
  • Limited Role for Policy: The implication that systematic policy is largely ineffective can be seen as a limitation, as it offers little guidance for policymakers seeking to stabilize the economy during times of distress. However, figures like Paul Volcker, whose tenure as Federal Reserve Chair involved a decisive approach to combating inflation, implicitly demonstrated the power of credible, consistent monetary policy in shaping expectations.

New Classical Macroeconomics vs. New Keynesian Economics

New classical macroeconomics and New Keynesian economics represent two dominant schools of thought within contemporary macroeconomics, both incorporating microfoundations and rational expectations. However, they differ significantly in their conclusions about market behavior and the effectiveness of government policy.

FeatureNew Classical MacroeconomicsNew Keynesian Economics
Core AssumptionMarkets clear instantly; prices and wages are fully flexible.Markets may not clear instantly; prices and wages are "sticky."
Policy EffectivenessSystematic monetary and fiscal policies are ineffective in influencing real economic variables (output, employment) in the long run. Only unanticipated policies have temporary real effects.Systematic monetary and fiscal policies can be effective in stabilizing the economy, especially in the short run, due to market imperfections.
Source of FluctuationsPrimarily unanticipated shocks to aggregate supply or aggregate demand.Market rigidities (e.g., sticky prices/wages), imperfect competition, coordination failures.
Role of GovernmentFocus on providing a stable and predictable policy environment; minimal role for active stabilization.Active stabilization policies (monetary and fiscal) are desirable to mitigate business cycle fluctuations and achieve full employment.

The confusion often arises because both schools utilize sophisticated modeling techniques and the assumption of rational expectations. However, New Keynesian economics introduces various market imperfections, such as menu costs, efficiency wages, and imperfect competition, which lead to price and wage stickiness. These rigidities allow aggregate demand shocks to have real effects and create a rationale for active government intervention, a key departure from the new classical view.

FAQs

What is the main idea behind New Classical Macroeconomics?

The main idea is that individuals and firms are rational agents who use all available information to make optimal decisions. Consequently, markets clear quickly, and prices and wages are flexible, meaning that systematic government policies cannot consistently influence real economic outcomes like output or unemployment in the long run. Only unexpected policy changes can have a temporary impact.

How does "rational expectations" fit into this theory?

Rational expectations is a cornerstone of new classical macroeconomics. It means that economic agents form their expectations about future economic variables, including future government policies, by using all relevant information efficiently and without systematic errors. This forward-looking behavior is crucial to the theory's conclusion that anticipated policies are ineffective.

Why does New Classical Macroeconomics argue that government policy is ineffective?

It argues that if a government policy (like increasing the money supply) is anticipated, rational agents will adjust their behavior immediately (e.g., by demanding higher wages or raising prices). This adjustment neutralizes the intended real effects of the policy, leading only to changes in nominal variables like the price level or nominal wages, without affecting real output or employment. This concept is often referred to as policy ineffectiveness.

What is the "Lucas Critique"?

The Lucas critique is a significant contribution from new classical macroeconomics. It states that the relationships observed in historical economic data, used to build traditional econometric models, are not stable if the underlying government policy rules change. Therefore, using such models to predict the effects of new policies can be misleading because people's behavior (and thus the model's parameters) will change in response to the new policy regime.

Does New Classical Macroeconomics support or