Skip to main content
← Back to P Definitions

Positive externality

What Is Positive Externality?

A positive externality occurs when the production or consumption of a good or service generates a benefit for a third party not directly involved in the market transaction, without that third party paying for the benefit. This concept is a core element within Economics and falls under the broader umbrella of Welfare Economics, which studies how the allocation of resources affects economic well-being. Unlike a typical market exchange where benefits are fully internalized by the buyer and seller, a positive externality creates a spillover effect that benefits others, leading to a situation where the market, left to its own devices, may not produce the socially optimal amount of the good or service. This divergence between private and social benefits often results in a market failure, indicating a less than efficient allocation of resources from society's perspective.

History and Origin

The concept of externalities, including positive externalities, was significantly developed by the British economist Arthur C. Pigou (1877-1959) in his seminal 1920 work, The Economics of Welfare. Pigou built upon earlier ideas to formalize how economic activities could impose costs or confer benefits on others that were not accounted for by the person undertaking the action. He argued that these external effects provide justification for government intervention. For positive externalities, Pigou advocated for subsidies to encourage activities that yielded broader societal gains, as individuals might not invest enough in them because they don't capture the full value of the benefits to society. His work laid the theoretical groundwork for understanding how markets can deviate from economic efficiency due to these unpriced effects. Arthur Pigou's work on externalities highlighted the importance of aligning private incentives with social welfare.

Key Takeaways

  • A positive externality provides benefits to third parties who are not directly involved in the production or consumption of a good or service.
  • These uncompensated benefits mean that the private market often under-produces goods with positive externalities.
  • Examples include education, vaccinations, and investments in public infrastructure.
  • Governments often address positive externalities through measures like subsidies or tax incentives to encourage their provision.
  • Correcting for positive externalities aims to achieve a more socially optimal allocation of resources.

Interpreting the Positive Externality

When a positive externality exists, the private benefits received by the consumer or producer of a good are less than the overall social benefits to society. This disparity means that, without intervention, the quantity produced or consumed will be below the socially desirable level. For example, an individual deciding whether to pursue higher education primarily considers their personal gains, such as increased earning potential or career opportunities. However, society also benefits from a more educated populace through increased productivity, innovation, and civic engagement.

The interpretation of a positive externality involves recognizing this divergence. Economists use the concepts of marginal private benefit (MPB) and marginal social benefit (MSB). The MSB curve lies above the MPB curve, reflecting the additional external benefits. The market naturally operates where marginal private benefit equals marginal private cost, leading to an underproduction of the good relative to the socially efficient quantity, where marginal social benefit equals marginal social cost. Understanding this gap is crucial for justifying policies designed to "internalize" the externality, meaning to make the external benefits part of the decision-making process. This can be achieved through mechanisms such as government subsidies that effectively lower the private cost or increase the private benefit, thereby incentivizing greater production or consumption.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a new technology developed by a small robotics firm. The firm invests heavily in research and development to create an innovative robotic arm that can perform complex surgical procedures with unprecedented precision. The immediate benefit of this invention accrues to the firm through sales and to hospitals and patients through improved surgical outcomes. However, the knowledge and patents generated by this firm's research also create a positive externality.

Other firms in the robotics industry can learn from the firm's advancements, even if they don't directly purchase its product. The new techniques or components pioneered by the firm might inspire further innovations in unrelated fields, such as manufacturing or space exploration, improving overall productivity and capabilities. The existence of this cutting-edge technology might also attract skilled engineers and researchers to the region, creating a local hub of expertise that benefits the entire community, irrespective of whether they interact directly with the pioneering firm. Without any external support, the initial firm might under-invest in such costly research because it cannot capture all of these widespread social benefits.

Practical Applications

Positive externalities are observed in various real-world scenarios, often leading to government intervention to encourage activities that generate them.

  • Education: A highly educated populace contributes to a more productive workforce, lower crime rates, and a more engaged citizenry. Individuals primarily consider their private returns from education, but the broader society reaps significant benefits. Governments worldwide provide public goods like free or subsidized public education to ensure a level of societal education that would not be achieved by the private market alone.
  • Healthcare: Vaccinations are a prime example. While an individual benefits directly from protection against disease, their vaccination also prevents the spread of illness to others, contributing to herd immunity. The economic benefits of childhood immunizations are substantial, extending beyond direct healthcare savings to broader societal well-being.
  • Research and Development (R&D): Innovations often create knowledge spillovers that benefit entire industries and society. A company's investment in R&D might lead to discoveries that can be adapted and built upon by other firms, even competitors, thereby advancing overall technological progress. Governments frequently offer subsidies or grants for R&D to promote innovation.
  • Infrastructure: Investments in public infrastructure, such as roads, bridges, and public transport systems, create widespread benefits beyond the direct users. Improved transportation networks reduce commuting times for workers, lower logistics costs for businesses, and enhance regional connectivity, fostering economic growth. These infrastructure investments contribute to overall productivity and quality of life.

Limitations and Criticisms

While recognizing positive externalities is crucial for identifying areas where markets underperform, accurately addressing them faces several limitations and criticisms. One significant challenge is the difficulty in precisely measuring the magnitude of external benefits. It is often complex to quantify the full societal value of, for example, a unit of education or a specific piece of scientific research. Without an accurate measure, setting the optimal level of government intervention, such as the size of a subsidy, becomes challenging. Over-subsidizing can lead to inefficient allocation of taxpayer funds, while under-subsidizing may still leave the positive externality unaddressed.

Another criticism centers on the potential for "government failure," where interventions may introduce new inefficiencies or unintended consequences. Political considerations can influence the allocation of subsidies or the scope of regulation, sometimes leading to rent-seeking behavior or misallocation of resources towards politically favored projects rather than those with the highest social benefit. Furthermore, policies designed to correct for externalities, such as Pigouvian taxes or subsidies, require a significant amount of information about costs and benefits, which can be hard to obtain in the real world. As discussed regarding limitations of Pigouvian solutions, knowing the marginal value or cost of an external effect is a considerable estimation challenge.

Moreover, the Coase Theorem offers an alternative perspective, suggesting that in the presence of clearly defined property rights and low transaction costs, private parties can bargain to reach an efficient outcome without government intervention. However, in many cases involving widespread positive externalities, the high number of affected parties and significant transaction costs make private bargaining impractical.

Positive Externality vs. Negative Externality

The primary distinction between a positive externality and a negative externality lies in the nature of the uncompensated effect on a third party.

FeaturePositive ExternalityNegative Externality
Effect on Third PartyBeneficialDetrimental
Market OutcomeUnderproduction (less than socially optimal)Overproduction (more than socially optimal)
Relationship between Private & SocialSocial benefits > Private benefitsSocial costs > Private costs
Typical Government InterventionSubsidies, grants, public provisionTaxes (Pigouvian), regulation, cap-and-trade systems
ExampleEducation, vaccinations, R&D spilloversPollution, noise, traffic congestion

While a positive externality leads to an under-provision of goods or services due to producers or consumers not capturing all the social benefits, a negative externality results in an over-provision because producers or consumers do not bear the full social costs of their actions. Both represent forms of market failure, but they require opposite policy responses to move the market towards the socially efficient outcome in terms of supply and demand.

FAQs

What is a positive externality in simple terms?

A positive externality is when an activity benefits someone else who wasn't directly involved and didn't pay for that benefit. Think of it as a free bonus or a spillover effect.

Why do positive externalities lead to market failure?

Positive externalities cause market failure because the market only accounts for private benefits, not the additional benefits enjoyed by society. As a result, the market produces less of the good than what would be ideal for society as a whole, leading to an inefficient allocation of resources.

What are some common examples of positive externalities?

Common examples include education, which benefits not only the individual but also society through a more skilled workforce; vaccinations, which protect the vaccinated person and reduce disease spread to others; and scientific research, where new discoveries can benefit many industries beyond the original researchers.

How do governments address positive externalities?

Governments often address positive externalities through policies like providing subsidies (financial aid) or tax incentives to encourage more production or consumption of the beneficial good or service. They may also directly provide public goods like public parks or education.

Can positive externalities become negative?

While the immediate impact of a positive externality is beneficial, the underlying activity can sometimes have negative aspects or lead to unintended consequences. However, the externality itself is defined by its net positive effect on the third party. For example, a new factory might bring jobs (a positive externality for the community) but also increase pollution (a negative externality). The factory's overall impact would be a combination of both positive and negative externalities.