Skip to main content
← Back to P Definitions

Preference relation

Preference Relation

A preference relation in Microeconomics and Consumer Theory is a formal concept used to describe how an individual ranks different bundles of goods or services according to their desirability. It essentially captures a person's tastes and priorities, indicating which options are considered "at least as good as" another, "strictly preferred to," or "indifferent to" in the context of decision making. These relations are fundamental to understanding consumer behavior and underpin many economic models that aim to predict choices.

History and Origin

The formalization of preference relations evolved significantly from earlier attempts to quantify satisfaction, such as utility theory. Initially, economists in the 19th century, like William Stanley Jevons and Carl Menger, conceived of utility as a cardinal (measurable) concept, believing it could be assigned a numerical value to represent pleasure or pain. However, problems with the direct measurement and interpersonal comparison of utility led to a shift in economic thought.10

By the 1930s and 1940s, the "ordinal revolution" in economics, propelled by thinkers like Vilfredo Pareto, John R. Hicks, and Roy Allen, moved away from cardinal utility, focusing instead on ranking choices.9 This meant that a consumer could state they preferred one bundle over another without needing to specify how much more they preferred it. Later, in 1938, Paul Samuelson introduced the concept of "revealed preference," arguing that preferences could be inferred from observed choices rather than relying on unobservable mental states. This approach provided a more empirical foundation for understanding how individuals make selections among available options.8,

Key Takeaways

  • A preference relation formally describes an individual's ranking of different options or bundles of goods.
  • It is a core concept in microeconomics, providing the basis for models of consumer choice.
  • Preference relations are characterized by fundamental properties, or axioms, such as completeness and transitivity, which ensure logical consistency.
  • The concept evolved from attempts to measure "utility" to a focus on observable rankings and choices.
  • Understanding preference relations helps predict how individuals might respond to changes in prices, income, or policy.

Formula and Calculation

While a preference relation is not a "formula" in the sense of a numerical calculation, it is defined by a set of properties or axioms that govern how preferences behave. For a binary relation denoted by ( \succsim ) (meaning "at least as good as") over a set of consumption bundles (X), the primary axioms ensuring a "rational" preference relation are:

  1. Completeness: For any two bundles ( A ) and ( B ) in ( X ), either ( A \succsim B ) (A is at least as good as B), or ( B \succsim A ) (B is at least as good as A), or both. This means an individual can always compare any two bundles.7,6
  2. Reflexivity: For any bundle ( A ) in ( X ), ( A \succsim A ). A bundle is at least as good as itself.
  3. Transitivity: For any three bundles ( A, B, C ) in ( X ), if ( A \succsim B ) and ( B \succsim C ), then ( A \succsim C ). This ensures consistency in rankings; if a consumer prefers A to B and B to C, they must prefer A to C.5,4

These axioms ensure a logical and consistent ordering of preferences, allowing for the construction of indifference curves and, under certain conditions, a utility function that represents these preferences.

Interpreting the Preference Relation

Interpreting a preference relation involves understanding how an individual's subjective evaluations translate into their choices. A "rational" preference relation, typically assumed in standard economic theory, means that an individual's rankings are consistent and well-defined. For example, if a person strictly prefers apples to bananas, and is indifferent between bananas and oranges, a transitive preference relation implies they must strictly prefer apples to oranges.3

The interpretation extends beyond simple "likes" and "dislikes" to imply a consistent structure that enables prediction. By assuming these properties, economists can model how consumers make optimization choices given their budget constraint. This framework helps explain why, for instance, an individual might choose less of a highly desired good if its price increases significantly, due to the implicit trade-offs defined by their preferences and available resources.

Hypothetical Example

Consider Sarah, who is deciding between different combinations of coffee and books.
Let:

  • Bundle A = 3 coffees, 1 book
  • Bundle B = 2 coffees, 2 books
  • Bundle C = 1 coffee, 3 books

Sarah's preferences are described as follows:

  • She prefers more books to coffee.
  • She values the variety of both.

Based on her subjective ranking:

  1. Sarah states she prefers Bundle B to Bundle A (( B \succ A )). This indicates that while Bundle A has more coffee, the extra book in Bundle B makes it more appealing to her.
  2. She also states she prefers Bundle B to Bundle C (( B \succ C )). This suggests that the balance of 2 coffees and 2 books is better for her than more books with less coffee.
  3. If asked to compare A and C, and her preferences are rational and exhibit transitivity, we would infer that she might prefer A to C (or be indifferent), even without a direct statement, because B is preferred to both, and A has more coffee than C, which she generally likes, albeit less than books. However, a more detailed understanding of her diminishing marginal rate of substitution would be needed to precisely predict her choice between A and C if they were the only options.

This simple example illustrates how a preference relation formally captures a person's ordering of choices, which can then be used to predict their behavior under different scenarios.

Practical Applications

Preference relations are foundational in various fields beyond pure microeconomics:

  • Market Research and Marketing: Companies use insights into consumer preferences to design products, set prices, and tailor advertising campaigns. By understanding consumer rankings of features, quality, and price points, businesses can optimize their offerings.
  • Public Policy: Governments analyze societal preferences to design effective policies, such as taxation, subsidies, and public goods provision. For example, understanding public preference for environmental quality versus economic growth can inform policy decisions.
  • Finance and Investing: Investors often exhibit preferences for risk and return. Concepts like risk aversion are direct applications of preference relations, guiding portfolio allocation and investment strategies.
  • Game Theory: In game theory, the outcomes of strategic interactions depend heavily on the preferences of the players involved. Predicting rational actions requires understanding each player's ordered preferences over possible results.
  • Behavioral Economics: While often critiquing the strict assumptions of rationality, behavioral economists still rely on understanding underlying preferences, even if those preferences are influenced by cognitive biases or heuristics. The theory of revealed preference is a key tool in this area, allowing economists to infer preferences from observed choices rather than from stated intentions.

Limitations and Criticisms

Despite their widespread use, preference relations and the rational choice theory built upon them face several criticisms:

  • Bounded Rationality: A significant critique comes from behavioral economics, which argues that individuals often do not possess the perfect information or cognitive ability to maintain perfectly consistent and transitive preferences in complex situations. Herbert Simon's concept of "bounded rationality" suggests that people make "satisficing" decisions rather than perfectly optimal ones, due to cognitive limits.
  • Context Dependency: Preferences can be highly context-dependent and are not always stable as assumed by traditional economic models. Framing effects, emotional states, and social influences can alter choices, leading to seemingly inconsistent preferences.
  • Endogenous Preferences: The standard theory assumes preferences are exogenous (given), but in reality, preferences can be shaped by advertising, social norms, past experiences, and available options. This makes predicting behavior more complex.
  • Measurement Challenges: While observable choices can reveal preferences, the precise nature of an individual's underlying preference relation, especially for non-market goods or complex trade-offs, remains challenging to fully ascertain.
  • Violation of Axioms: Empirical studies sometimes show violations of core axioms like transitivity in real-world decision making, particularly in situations involving uncertainty or psychological biases. Behavioral economists like Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky have highlighted these deviations, arguing that traditional rational choice theory is unrealistic in its assumptions about human behavior.2

Preference Relation vs. Utility Function

While closely related and often used interchangeably in simplified contexts, a preference relation and a utility function are distinct concepts in economics.

A preference relation is a primitive concept, a fundamental ordering by which an individual ranks alternatives. It describes which bundle is preferred over another, or if they are indifferent, without assigning numerical values. For instance, "Apple is preferred to Banana." It is a binary relation (e.g., ( \succsim ) for "at least as good as") that establishes an ordering over a set of consumption bundles.

A utility function, on the other hand, is a mathematical representation that assigns a numerical value (utility) to each bundle of goods, such that if bundle A is preferred to bundle B, then the utility assigned to A is greater than the utility assigned to B. It provides a convenient way to represent an individual's preferences numerically, making them amenable to mathematical optimization techniques. For example, if ( U(Apple) = 10 ) and ( U(Banana) = 5 ), then Apple is preferred. Importantly, the absolute numerical values of utility have no intrinsic meaning, and only their ordinal ranking matters; a utility function is said to represent a preference relation if it preserves the order of the preferences. Not every preference relation can be represented by a utility function, though common economic assumptions like completeness and continuity often allow for such a representation.1

FAQs

What does it mean for preferences to be "rational"?

In economics, "rational" preferences are those that satisfy certain axioms, primarily completeness and transitivity. Completeness means you can compare any two options, and transitivity means your comparisons are consistent (if you prefer A to B and B to C, you must prefer A to C). This doesn't mean decisions are always "smart" or emotionally detached, but rather internally consistent.

How do economists measure preference relations if they can't be directly observed?

Economists primarily infer preference relations through observed choices, using the concept of revealed preference. If a consumer chooses a specific bundle of goods when other affordable options were available, it is "revealed" that they prefer the chosen bundle. By observing many choices under different budget constraint scenarios, economists can deduce underlying preferences.

What is the difference between a strong preference and a weak preference?

A "weak preference" (( \succsim )) indicates that one option is "at least as good as" another. This allows for the possibility of indifference (meaning both options are equally preferred). A "strong preference" or "strict preference" (( \succ )) means that one option is "strictly better than" another, with no possibility of indifference. If you have a weak preference for A over B, but not a weak preference for B over A, then you have a strict preference for A over B.

Why are preference relations important for understanding consumer choice?

Preference relations are crucial because they provide the foundation for understanding how individuals make selections in a world of scarcity. By formalizing how people rank goods and services, economists can build economic models that predict consumer behavior in response to changes in prices, income, and other market conditions, leading to insights into demand, supply, and market equilibrium.