Skip to main content
← Back to R Definitions

Real rigidities

What Is Real Rigidities?

Real rigidities refer to factors in an economy that prevent prices and wages from adjusting quickly to their new market-clearing levels, even in the absence of nominal rigidities, which typically relate to money or monetary policy. These hindrances are structural, affecting the relative prices or quantities of goods, services, or factors of production, and fall under the broader category of macroeconomics. Unlike nominal rigidities, which stem from the costs of changing nominal prices, real rigidities arise from real-world impediments to adjustment, such as imperfect competition, information asymmetries, or coordination failures. The presence of real rigidities means that even if all agents instantaneously adjusted their nominal prices to reflect changes in aggregate monetary conditions, the underlying real factors would still prevent immediate and full adjustment of relative prices and quantities, thereby influencing the economy's economic equilibrium.

History and Origin

The concept of real rigidities gained prominence with the development of New Keynesian economics, which sought to provide microfoundations for macroeconomic phenomena like involuntary unemployment and the non-neutrality of money. While classical economics assumed rapid and complete market adjustments, and early Keynesian thought emphasized nominal rigidities like wage stickiness, New Keynesian models explicitly incorporated various forms of real rigidities. This theoretical evolution highlighted that even if nominal prices could change without cost, other real-world frictions could still lead to persistent deviations from full employment or optimal aggregate supply. For instance, academic work has explored how various real rigidities can influence the slope and behavior of the Phillips curve, which illustrates the relationship between inflation and unemployment.4 This ongoing research helps refine understanding of how economic shocks propagate through the economy.

Key Takeaways

  • Real rigidities are structural impediments preventing relative prices and quantities from adjusting rapidly.
  • They exist even if nominal prices can change freely, stemming from factors like imperfect competition or coordination problems.
  • These rigidities contribute to the stickiness of the economy, affecting how quickly it responds to shocks.
  • Understanding real rigidities is crucial for analyzing business cycles and the effectiveness of macroeconomic policies.

Interpreting Real Rigidities

Understanding real rigidities involves recognizing their impact on economic agents' behavior and the broader economy's responsiveness. When real rigidities are significant, it implies that the economy's output gap can persist for longer periods following a shock, as the underlying real components (like production costs or labor supply) do not adjust smoothly. For instance, if firms face high marginal cost of adjusting production levels, they might be slow to expand or contract output, even if demand conditions change significantly. This slow adjustment can prolong economic downturns or recoveries, making macroeconomic stabilization efforts more challenging. Policymakers interpreting economic data often look for signs of these deeper structural issues that might impede rapid market clearing.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a hypothetical economy reliant on a single dominant industry, say, specialized robotics manufacturing. Due to the highly specialized nature of the labor force and the unique machinery involved, retraining workers or retooling factories to produce different goods is extremely difficult and costly. This represents a significant real rigidity in the form of low labor and capital intensity mobility.

If there's a sudden global shift in consumer preferences away from specialized robotics towards, for example, biotechnology, the robotics industry faces a sharp decline in demand. Even if nominal wages for robotics engineers could be instantly cut, and the prices of robotics components could drop, the highly specific skills of the engineers and the immobility of the machinery mean they cannot easily transition to biotechnology. The firms in the robotics sector would find it very difficult to reduce their production costs sufficiently or reallocate their resources. This deep-seated inability to adjust production or labor effectively, despite price signals, exemplifies a real rigidity, leading to sustained high unemployment rate in the robotics sector and an overall slower economic adjustment to the new demand landscape.

Practical Applications

Real rigidities have significant practical implications for economic analysis and policy formulation, particularly in macroeconomics. They are often incorporated into sophisticated economic models, such as Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models, to better capture the sticky nature of real economic variables in response to shocks. For central banks, understanding real rigidities helps in forecasting inflation dynamics and calibrating [monetary policy](https://diversification.com/term/monetary policy) responses. If real rigidities are prevalent, monetary policy might have a more delayed or attenuated effect on real economic activity.3 Similarly, governments consider real rigidities when designing fiscal policy, recognizing that structural impediments can limit the effectiveness of stimulus measures or lead to longer recovery periods during business cycles. International organizations, such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF), frequently highlight the importance of addressing structural rigidities in national economies to foster long-term growth and resilience, particularly in regions like the Euro area, where such issues can hinder economic performance and adjustment to external shocks.2

Limitations and Criticisms

While the concept of real rigidities provides valuable insights into macroeconomic behavior, identifying and quantifying them empirically can be challenging. It is often difficult to disentangle the effects of real rigidities from those of nominal rigidities or other market imperfections. Critics sometimes point out that the precise mechanisms through which real rigidities operate, such as information frictions or coordination failures, can be abstract and difficult to measure directly. Furthermore, the degree and impact of real rigidities can vary significantly across industries, sectors, and economies, making a universal application of theoretical models complex. For instance, discussions around the "flattening" of the Phillips curve often involve debates about whether changes in the nature of rigidities—both nominal and real—are at play, and what this implies for monetary policy. Thi1s ongoing debate underscores the complexities in fully understanding and modeling these economic phenomena.

Real Rigidities vs. Nominal Rigidities

Real rigidities and nominal rigidities both contribute to the slow adjustment of an economy to shocks, but they differ fundamentally in their nature. Nominal rigidities refer to the stickiness of prices or wages in nominal terms, meaning their resistance to changing in monetary units. This is often due to menu costs (the costs associated with changing prices), implicit contracts, or money illusion. For example, if a company is reluctant to change its advertised prices due to the cost of reprinting catalogs, that is a nominal rigidity.

In contrast, real rigidities refer to factors that prevent relative prices and quantities from adjusting even if nominal prices could change freely. These are structural issues related to the real economy, such as imperfect competition preventing price flexibility relative to costs, or production technologies that make it costly to adjust output or reallocate resources. For example, if workers resist real wage cuts (their purchasing power) even when labor demand falls, that is a form of real rigidity, specifically sticky wages. While nominal rigidities are about the difficulty of changing the number on a price tag, real rigidities are about the difficulty of changing the real value of goods, services, or factors of production relative to others, or the quantity of real activity.

FAQs

Why are real rigidities important for understanding economic downturns?

Real rigidities are crucial because they explain why economies might experience prolonged periods of unemployment or underutilized capacity during downturns, even if monetary conditions are favorable. They prevent a quick return to full employment by making it difficult for resources like labor and capital to shift efficiently in response to reduced aggregate demand.

What are some examples of real rigidities?

Examples include imperfect competition among firms, which can lead to prices being marked up over marginal costs and thus less flexible; costly adjustment of capital or labor, making it hard for businesses to quickly expand or shrink; and information asymmetries, where one party in a transaction has more or better information than the other, impeding efficient market functioning. price stickiness in markets due to strategic interactions is another common example.

How do real rigidities affect monetary policy?

Real rigidities can diminish the effectiveness of monetary policy. If firms face significant real costs in adjusting their output or prices, changes in interest rates initiated by monetary policy may take longer to translate into desired changes in real economic activity, such as employment and output. Central banks must account for these delays and muted responses when setting policy.