Skip to main content
← Back to R Definitions

Regulation q

What Is Regulation Q?

Regulation Q was a rule issued by the Federal Reserve Board that historically prohibited the payment of interest rates on demand deposits and set maximum interest rate ceilings on other types of deposit accounts, such as savings accounts and time deposits. This aspect of Regulation Q falls under the broader category of financial regulation, specifically pertaining to banking and deposit-taking institutions. While the original intent was to foster financial stability by limiting interbank competition for deposits, its most significant provisions were phased out or repealed by 2011. Today, a distinct version of Regulation Q, updated in 2013, sets out capital requirements for banks.

History and Origin

The initial version of Regulation Q was promulgated by the Federal Reserve Board on August 29, 1933, as a direct result of Section 11 of the Banking Act of 1933, commonly known as the Glass-Steagall Act. This landmark legislation was enacted during the Great Depression following a period of widespread bank failures.31,30 The primary purpose of Regulation Q was to curb what policymakers at the time perceived as excessive and risky competition among banks for deposits, believing that high interest payments forced banks into speculative and unsound lending practices to cover their costs.,29

The regulation banned interest on checking accounts and imposed ceilings on savings and time deposits.,28 This move aimed to prevent a recurrence of the financial instability seen in the early 1930s.27 However, these interest rate caps had unintended consequences, notably fostering the rise of alternative financial instruments not subject to the same restrictions, such as money market funds, which offered higher returns to depositors.,26 The ceilings for savings and time deposits were gradually phased out between 1980 and 1986 by the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980.,25,24 The prohibition on interest for demand deposits, the last major component of the original Regulation Q, was effectively repealed on July 21, 2011, by the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act.,23,22

Key Takeaways

  • Regulation Q was originally established in 1933 to prohibit interest payments on demand deposits and cap interest rates on other deposit accounts.
  • Its primary goal was to reduce interbank competition for deposits, which was thought to lead to risky lending and contribute to financial instability.
  • The regulation inadvertently led to the growth of alternative financial products, like money market funds, that offered higher returns.
  • The interest rate ceilings were phased out by 1986, and the ban on interest-bearing demand deposits was repealed in 2011.,21
  • A newer version of Regulation Q, issued in 2013, focuses on minimum capital requirements for banks.

Interpreting the Regulation Q

In its historical context, interpreting Regulation Q meant understanding its constraints on how banks could compete for customer deposits. For depositors, it meant limited or no interest earned on checking accounts and capped rates on savings and time deposits, often below market rates. For banks, it meant competition shifted from pricing deposits to other factors, such as branch networks, customer service, or offering non-monetary incentives.20

In its modern form, the current Regulation Q focuses on setting capital requirements for regulated institutions. This version of the regulation is interpreted as a measure to ensure banks maintain sufficient financial buffers to absorb losses, thereby enhancing the resilience of the banking system and contributing to broader financial stability.

Practical Applications

Historically, Regulation Q significantly impacted the structure and behavior of the U.S. banking industry. It limited market competition among banks for deposits by preventing them from using interest rates as a primary competitive tool.19,18 This led to banks competing through other means, such as offering free services or promotional gifts like toasters or televisions to attract customers.17

Its repeal in 2011 allowed banks to pay interest on demand deposits, changing the competitive landscape for financial institutions.16,15 This shift increased competition for customer funds, encouraging banks to innovate with new deposit accounts and services. The modern iteration of Regulation Q, concerning bank capital, is applied to ensure that banks hold adequate reserves to absorb potential losses, which is a critical aspect of prudential regulation designed to prevent systemic financial crisis.

Limitations and Criticisms

While intended to prevent speculative banking and ensure stability, the historical Regulation Q faced significant limitations and criticisms. One major critique was that it suppressed interest rates on bank deposits below market levels, effectively acting as a form of "financial repression.",14 This discouraged savings and penalized depositors. It also limited banks' ability to attract funds and respond to market forces, making them less competitive compared to non-bank financial institutions like money market funds, which were not subject to the same restrictions and could offer higher yields.,13

The regulation also hindered market competition within the banking sector, as banks could not differentiate themselves based on deposit rates.12,11 This often benefited larger banks, which could leverage their existing customer base and branch networks, while smaller banks struggled to compete effectively.10 Ultimately, these limitations led to calls for deregulation and the eventual phasing out and repeal of the original Regulation Q provisions.9,8

Regulation Q vs. Glass-Steagall Act

Regulation Q and the Glass-Steagall Act are distinct but historically interconnected pieces of financial regulation enacted in the 1930s. The Glass-Steagall Act, formally known as the Banking Act of 1933, was a broader legislative measure that primarily aimed to separate commercial banking from investment banking activities.7, Its goal was to protect depositor funds from the speculative risks associated with securities underwriting and trading.,6

Regulation Q, on the other hand, was a specific rule established under the authority granted by the Glass-Steagall Act (and subsequent legislation like the Banking Act of 1935) that addressed the payment of interest on deposit accounts.,5 While Glass-Steagall tackled structural separation within the banking industry, Regulation Q focused on pricing controls for deposits. The Glass-Steagall Act's key provisions regarding the separation of commercial and investment banking were largely repealed in 1999 by the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act, while the interest rate provisions of Regulation Q were phased out or repealed later, in 2011.,4

FAQs

Why was Regulation Q originally implemented?

Regulation Q was implemented in 1933 as part of the broader Banking Act of 1933 (Glass-Steagall Act) to prevent what was perceived as destructive competition among banks for deposit accounts. Policymakers believed that banks paying high interest rates on deposits were forced to engage in riskier lending to cover their costs, contributing to bank failures.

When was Regulation Q repealed?

The specific provisions of Regulation Q that capped interest rates on savings accounts and time deposits were gradually phased out between 1980 and 1986. The final major component, the prohibition on paying interest on demand deposits, was repealed on July 21, 2011, by the Dodd-Frank Act.,3,2

What replaced the original Regulation Q?

While the original interest rate-setting aspects of Regulation Q were repealed, the overall framework of financial regulation evolved. Today, a separate version of Regulation Q exists, which outlines capital requirements and capital adequacy standards for banks, reflecting modern regulatory priorities focused on bank resilience.

Did Regulation Q affect consumers?

Yes, Regulation Q directly affected consumers by limiting the interest they could earn on their deposit accounts. For decades, consumers received little to no interest on checking accounts and capped rates on savings, which often encouraged them to seek alternatives like money market funds for higher returns.,1