Skip to main content
← Back to A Definitions

Adjusted credit multiplier

What Is Adjusted Credit Multiplier?

The Adjusted Credit Multiplier is a concept within monetary policy that seeks to describe the process by which commercial banks create new loans and, consequently, expand the money supply in an economy, while taking into account factors beyond simple reserve requirements. Unlike the traditional money multiplier, which often assumes a fixed relationship between reserves and deposits, the Adjusted Credit Multiplier incorporates real-world complexities such as banks' willingness to lend, borrower demand, and the impact of central bank actions on excess reserves. It provides a more nuanced view of credit creation within the broader framework of financial economics.

History and Origin

The concept of a credit multiplier has its roots in the theory of fractional reserve banking, where banks hold only a fraction of their deposits in reserve and lend out the rest. Historically, economists developed the simple "money multiplier" model to explain how an initial deposit could lead to a multiplied expansion of the money supply through successive rounds of lending and redepositing. However, this traditional model faced increasing criticism for its oversimplification, particularly following the 2008 financial crisis. Critics argued that the simplified money multiplier did not adequately capture how banks actually operate, nor the evolving role of the central bank in influencing credit.

The move towards an "Adjusted Credit Multiplier" reflects a refinement in economic thought, acknowledging that factors like bank preferences, loan demand, and unconventional monetary policies (such as quantitative easing) significantly influence the actual expansion of credit. Central banks themselves have acknowledged the limitations of the simple money multiplier in predicting changes in the money supply, recognizing that factors beyond just reserves play a crucial role.11, 12

Key Takeaways

  • The Adjusted Credit Multiplier offers a more realistic view of how banks expand credit compared to the traditional money multiplier.
  • It accounts for factors such as banks' voluntary holdings of excess reserves and the demand for lending.
  • Central bank policies, including interest rates on reserves and asset purchases, significantly influence the Adjusted Credit Multiplier.
  • Understanding this multiplier helps in analyzing the effectiveness of monetary policy in influencing economic activity.

Formula and Calculation

While there isn't one universally accepted "Adjusted Credit Multiplier" formula due to its adaptive nature, it can be conceptualized as a modification of the basic money multiplier. The traditional money multiplier ($M$) is often presented as the reciprocal of the reserve ratio ($RR$):

M=1RRM = \frac{1}{RR}

However, the Adjusted Credit Multiplier incorporates additional behavioral and regulatory factors. A more comprehensive, though still simplified, representation might consider the desired excess reserve ratio ($ER/D$) held by banks and the currency-to-deposit ratio ($C/D$) held by the public.

Let:

  • $m_a$ = Adjusted Credit Multiplier
  • $RR$ = Required Reserve Ratio
  • $ER/D$ = Excess Reserve to Deposit Ratio (voluntary reserves held by banks)
  • $C/D$ = Currency to Deposit Ratio (cash held by the public relative to deposits)

Then a generalized Adjusted Credit Multiplier could be expressed as:

ma=1+C/DRR+ER/D+C/Dm_a = \frac{1 + C/D}{RR + ER/D + C/D}

This formula illustrates that the total expansion of the money supply is not solely dependent on the reserve requirements set by the central bank, but also on how much currency the public chooses to hold and how many excess reserves banks choose to retain rather than lend out.

Interpreting the Adjusted Credit Multiplier

Interpreting the Adjusted Credit Multiplier involves understanding the dynamic interplay of factors that influence bank lending and the broader money supply. A higher Adjusted Credit Multiplier suggests that each unit of the monetary base can support a larger amount of credit and deposits in the economy. Conversely, a lower multiplier indicates a more constrained credit creation process.

For instance, if commercial banks choose to hold significant excess reserves, perhaps due to perceived risks or attractive interest rates paid on these reserves by the central bank, the actual credit multiplier will be lower than the theoretical maximum implied by mandatory reserve requirements alone. This was observed during and after the 2008 financial crisis, where despite massive injections of reserves by the Federal Reserve, bank lending did not expand proportionally due to banks holding substantial excess reserves.10 This highlights that central banks' ability to influence the money supply is not absolute but is mediated by banks' and the public's behavior.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a hypothetical economy where the central bank sets a reserve requirements of 10% ($RR = 0.10$).

In a simplified traditional money multiplier model, an initial deposit of $100 would theoretically lead to a total money supply expansion of $100 \times (1/0.10) = $1,000.

Now, let's introduce adjustments for the Adjusted Credit Multiplier. Suppose commercial banks, facing economic uncertainty, decide to voluntarily hold an additional 5% of their deposits as excess reserves ($ER/D = 0.05$). Additionally, consumers tend to hold 20% of their money as physical currency rather than depositing it ($C/D = 0.20$).

Using the adjusted formula:

ma=1+0.200.10+0.05+0.20=1.200.353.43m_a = \frac{1 + 0.20}{0.10 + 0.05 + 0.20} = \frac{1.20}{0.35} \approx 3.43

With an initial $100 deposit, the total theoretical expansion of the money supply would now be approximately $100 \times 3.43 = $343. This significantly lower figure illustrates how factors like bank behavior and public preferences can dampen the credit creation process compared to the simple multiplier.

Practical Applications

The Adjusted Credit Multiplier is a crucial concept in understanding how monetary policy decisions translate into real-world economic growth and inflation. Policymakers at a central bank utilize an understanding of this adjusted multiplier when setting interest rates and implementing tools like quantitative easing.

For instance, during periods of economic contraction, a central bank might lower interest rates or expand its balance sheet through asset purchases to inject reserves into the banking system, hoping to encourage lending and stimulate the economy. However, if banks are hesitant to lend due to high risk perceptions or if there's weak demand for loans from businesses and consumers, the Adjusted Credit Multiplier will be low, limiting the effectiveness of these measures. The regulations imposed by international frameworks like Basel III also influence banks' willingness and capacity to lend by setting capital and liquidity requirements. These requirements can directly affect the amount of credit banks are able to extend, thus impacting the Adjusted Credit Multiplier.9

Limitations and Criticisms

Despite offering a more refined perspective, the Adjusted Credit Multiplier still faces limitations. The primary criticism is that even this adjusted model may not fully capture the complex, endogenous nature of money creation in modern banking systems. Many economists and central bankers argue that bank lending often drives deposit creation, rather than deposits being a prerequisite for lending ("loans create deposits"). This challenges the sequential "reserves first" view inherent in multiplier models.7, 8

Furthermore, the behavioral components of the Adjusted Credit Multiplier, such as banks' desired excess reserves and the public's currency holdings, can be highly variable and difficult to predict, especially during times of financial instability. For example, during crises, banks may choose to hold vast amounts of excess reserves, effectively breaking the link between monetary base expansion and credit growth, as seen in the aftermath of the 2008 crisis.6 This variability can render the multiplier unstable and reduce its predictive power as a precise tool for monetary policy.5

Adjusted Credit Multiplier vs. Money Multiplier

The Adjusted Credit Multiplier and the Money Multiplier are both concepts used in financial economics to explain how a fractional reserve banking system can expand the money supply through lending. However, they differ significantly in their assumptions and applicability:

FeatureMoney MultiplierAdjusted Credit Multiplier
Core AssumptionBanks lend out all excess reserves; public redeposits all funds.Accounts for banks holding voluntary excess reserves and public holding currency.
Formula SimplicitySimple: 1 / Reserve RatioMore complex, incorporating behavioral ratios (e.g., excess reserves to deposits, currency to deposits).
RealismHighly simplified; often seen as a theoretical ideal.More realistic, reflecting actual banking behavior and monetary conditions.
Predictive PowerLimited in real-world scenarios due to unaddressed factors.Better, but still imperfect, for understanding real-world credit creation.
Relevance to PolicyLess relevant for guiding modern monetary policy decisions.More relevant for understanding challenges in implementing monetary policy, especially during crises.

The Money Multiplier provides a foundational understanding of how banks can multiply deposits, while the Adjusted Credit Multiplier aims to bridge the gap between this theoretical understanding and the complexities of actual credit creation in the economy.

FAQs

How does the central bank influence the Adjusted Credit Multiplier?

The central bank influences the Adjusted Credit Multiplier through various monetary policy tools. By setting reserve requirements, adjusting key interest rates (like the rate paid on excess reserves), or engaging in quantitative easing, the central bank can impact banks' incentives to lend and the overall availability of reserves, thereby affecting the multiplier.3, 4

Why did the traditional money multiplier become less relevant?

The traditional money multiplier became less relevant because it did not accurately reflect how commercial banks operate in practice, particularly in modern financial systems. It assumes that banks are strictly reserve-constrained and will always lend out all available excess reserves, which is often not the case. Factors like bank profitability, risk aversion, and weak loan demand can lead banks to hold reserves rather than lend, breaking the direct link assumed by the simple multiplier.1, 2

Does a higher Adjusted Credit Multiplier always lead to economic growth?

Not necessarily. While a higher Adjusted Credit Multiplier indicates a greater potential for money supply expansion and lending, actual economic growth depends on many factors, including productive investment opportunities, consumer confidence, and overall demand for goods and services. If increased lending finances unproductive activities or if there is insufficient demand, the impact on economic growth may be limited, or it could even contribute to inflation.