Skip to main content
← Back to E Definitions

Expected value

What Is Expected Value?

Expected value represents the anticipated average outcome of a random process or variable if that process were repeated many times. In the realm of probability and statistics and decision theory, expected value provides a quantitative measure used to evaluate potential outcomes and make informed choices, particularly under conditions of uncertainty. It is a weighted average of all possible outcomes, where each outcome's value is multiplied by its likelihood of occurring, and these products are summed. Investors and analysts frequently utilize expected value to assess potential gains or losses in various financial scenarios, making it a cornerstone in financial analysis and investment decisions.

History and Origin

The concept of expected value famously emerged in the mid-17th century through a correspondence between two renowned mathematicians, Blaise Pascal and Pierre de Fermat. Their collaboration was sparked by the "problem of points," a challenge posed by French nobleman Antoine Gombaud, also known as Chevalier de Méré, concerning how to fairly divide stakes in an unfinished game of chance. This problem required determining the value of each player's expectation based on the number of rounds won and the rounds needed to win. Pascal and Fermat's rigorous analysis of this gambling problem led to the foundational principles of modern probability theory, including the explicit reasoning about what is now known as expected value. T12heir work provided a systematic way to quantify the value of uncertain future events by considering the magnitude of a potential event weighted by its likelihood of occurrence.

11## Key Takeaways

  • Expected value is the long-term average outcome of a random process if repeated many times.
  • It is calculated by multiplying each possible outcome by its probability and summing these products.
  • Expected value is a fundamental tool in risk management, financial modeling, and decision-making under uncertainty.
  • It helps assess the potential average return or cost of an investment or decision.
  • While a powerful tool, expected value has limitations, particularly when individual preferences and non-monetary factors are considered.

Formula and Calculation

The formula for expected value ((E[X])) of a discrete random variable (X) is calculated as the sum of all possible values of the variable multiplied by their respective probabilities:

E[X]=i=1nxiP(xi)E[X] = \sum_{i=1}^{n} x_i \cdot P(x_i)

Where:

  • (E[X]) = Expected value of the random variable (X)
  • (x_i) = The (i)-th possible outcome or value
  • (P(x_i)) = The probability of the (i)-th outcome occurring
  • (n) = The total number of possible outcomes

This formula effectively provides a weighted average, where the weights are the probabilities of each outcome.

Interpreting the Expected Value

Interpreting the expected value involves understanding that it represents the average outcome over a large number of trials or repetitions. It is not necessarily an outcome that will occur in any single instance. For example, if an investment has an expected value of $100, it does not mean that every time you make that investment, you will gain exactly $100. Instead, it suggests that if you were to make this investment many times, the average gain across all those instances would converge to $100. This concept is closely related to the Law of Large Numbers, which states that as the number of trials increases, the observed average of results from a sample will approach the expected value.

In decision-making, a positive expected value generally indicates a favorable long-term prospect, while a negative expected value suggests an unfavorable one. However, this interpretation must be balanced with considerations of risk tolerance and other qualitative factors.

Hypothetical Example

Consider an investor evaluating a potential venture into a new market. There are three possible scenarios for the financial outcome over the next year:

  1. Success: A 60% chance of a $500,000 profit.
  2. Moderate Growth: A 25% chance of a $100,000 profit.
  3. Failure: A 15% chance of a $200,000 loss.

To calculate the expected value of this venture, the investor would apply the formula:

E[Venture]=(0.60×$500,000)+(0.25×$100,000)+(0.15×$200,000)E[Venture]=$300,000+$25,000$30,000E[Venture]=$295,000E[\text{Venture}] = (0.60 \times \$500,000) + (0.25 \times \$100,000) + (0.15 \times -\$200,000) \\ E[\text{Venture}] = \$300,000 + \$25,000 - \$30,000 \\ E[\text{Venture}] = \$295,000

The expected value of this venture is $295,000. This means that, over many similar ventures, the average profit is anticipated to be $295,000 per venture. This calculation provides a crucial input for scenario analysis and informs whether the venture aligns with the investor's financial objectives.

Practical Applications

Expected value is a versatile tool with numerous applications across finance, economics, and various other fields. In investing, it is integral to evaluating potential returns from different assets or portfolios, helping investors make informed choices. F10inancial professionals use expected value in portfolio optimization to construct portfolios that aim to maximize returns for a given level of risk. F9or example, the expected return of a stock or a portfolio is a key component in forecasting future performance.

8Beyond investment, expected value plays a role in:

  • Risk Management: Businesses use it to estimate potential losses from various risks, enabling them to allocate resources effectively for mitigation.
    *7 Insurance: Actuaries calculate expected losses from insured events to determine appropriate premiums.
  • Capital Budgeting: Companies assess the expected profitability of different projects and investments.
  • Game Theory: Analyzing outcomes in strategic interactions.
  • Algorithmic Trading: Developing strategies that exploit statistically favorable opportunities.

In these contexts, expected value provides a quantitative framework for financial modeling and assessing the viability of decisions. Morningstar provides further insight into how expected return, which is derived using expected value, is applied in portfolio forecasting.

6## Limitations and Criticisms

Despite its wide application, expected value has several notable limitations and criticisms, particularly when applied to real-world human decision-making. One primary criticism is that it assumes individuals are risk-neutral, meaning they are indifferent to risk and only focus on the average monetary outcome. However, in reality, most individuals are either risk-averse (preferring lower variability for a given expected return) or, in some contexts, risk-seeking.

5Furthermore, expected value calculations often rely on historical data and probabilistic assumptions that may not accurately predict future events, especially unforeseen ones. I4t also struggles to account for the subjective value or "utility" that individuals place on outcomes, which can differ significantly from their objective monetary value. For instance, the St. Petersburg Paradox illustrates a scenario where a game has an infinite expected monetary value, yet most people would not pay a large sum to play it, highlighting that people consider factors beyond mere monetary expectation.

3These limitations led to the development of alternative theories in behavioral economics, such as Prospect Theory, proposed by Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky. Prospect Theory suggests that individuals evaluate outcomes based on gains and losses relative to a reference point, and that people are generally more sensitive to losses than to equivalent gains (loss aversion). T2his theory, among others, attempts to describe actual human behavior more accurately by incorporating psychological factors and cognitive biases that influence choices under uncertainty.

Expected Value vs. Expected Utility

While often confused, expected value and expected utility are distinct concepts in decision theory. Expected value focuses purely on the arithmetic mean of potential monetary or quantitative outcomes, weighted by their probabilities. It is an objective, numerical measure of what one might "expect" on average.

In contrast, expected utility theory acknowledges that the subjective value, or utility, of money can vary for individuals. It suggests that people make decisions by maximizing their expected utility, which is the sum of the probabilities of each outcome multiplied by the utility derived from that outcome, rather than its objective monetary value. For example, gaining $1,000 might provide significant utility to someone with very little money, but only marginal additional utility to a billionaire. Expected utility incorporates an individual's risk preferences (e.g., risk aversion) into the decision-making process, providing a more nuanced framework for understanding why individuals might choose an option with a lower expected monetary value if it offers greater subjective satisfaction or less risk.

1## FAQs

What is the primary purpose of calculating expected value?

The primary purpose of calculating expected value is to determine the long-term average outcome of a situation involving uncertainty. It helps in making quantitative decision-making by providing a single, representative number for the anticipated result if a process were to be repeated numerous times.

How does probability relate to expected value?

Probability is a core component of expected value. Each possible outcome is weighted by its probability of occurrence. Without assigning probabilities to each scenario, it would be impossible to calculate the expected value, as it is fundamentally a probability-weighted average of outcomes. It integrates the likelihood of events with their potential magnitudes.

Can expected value be negative?

Yes, expected value can be negative. A negative expected value indicates that, on average, the outcome is expected to be a loss. For example, in a game of chance where the potential losses outweigh the potential gains, adjusted for their probabilities, the expected value would be negative. This means that, over many trials, one would anticipate losing money on average.

Is expected value always the best decision-making criterion?

Not always. While expected value is a powerful quantitative tool, it assumes risk-neutrality. It does not account for individual preferences, risk tolerance, or the subjective utility people derive from different outcomes. For situations involving significant risk or personal preferences, concepts like expected utility theory or insights from behavioral economics may provide a more comprehensive framework for decision-making.