Skip to main content
← Back to M Definitions

Money neutrality

Money Neutrality

What Is Money Neutrality?

Money neutrality is an economic theory asserting that changes in the aggregate money supply only affect nominal variables within an economy, such as prices, wages, and exchange rates, without impacting real variables like output, employment, or Gross Domestic Product. This concept is a core idea in Monetary economics, suggesting that money itself is a "veil" over real economic activity. In a world of perfect money neutrality, an increase in the money supply would lead to a proportional increase in all prices, leaving the purchasing power of individuals and the relative prices of goods and services unchanged. The theory implies that monetary policy cannot influence the real economy in the long run, only its price level. When money neutrality holds, shifts in the money supply only impact aggregate demand in nominal terms, while aggregate supply remains determined by real factors like technology, labor, and capital.

History and Origin

The concept of money neutrality traces its roots back to classical economics, particularly the ideas of the 18th-century Scottish philosopher and economist David Hume. In his 1752 essay "Of Money," Hume explored the relationship between the quantity of money and price levels, observing that an increase in the money supply, while initially stimulating trade, would ultimately only lead to higher prices, leaving real economic activity unaffected in the long run.12 Hume's observations laid much of the groundwork for what would later become known as the Quantity theory of money. While the term "neutrality of money" itself was later coined by Austrian economist Friedrich A. Hayek in 1931, the underlying principle that changes in the money stock primarily affect nominal variables has been a staple of classical economic thought for centuries.,11

Key Takeaways

  • Money neutrality posits that changes in the money supply affect only nominal variables (prices, wages) but not real variables (output, employment) in the long run.
  • It is a foundational concept in classical economics and the quantity theory of money.
  • The theory implies that monetary policy cannot stimulate long-term economic growth or alter real economic outcomes.
  • Modern economic theories often challenge strict money neutrality, especially in the short run, citing factors like sticky prices and wages.
  • Despite critiques, the concept remains important for understanding the long-term implications of monetary policy.

Interpreting Money Neutrality

Interpreting money neutrality involves understanding its implications for how the economy responds to changes in the money supply. If money is truly neutral, then actions by a central bank to increase or decrease the money supply would only lead to proportional changes in the overall price level, rather than altering the production of goods and services or the level of employment. For instance, if the money supply doubles, the theory suggests that all prices—from the cost of a loaf of bread to an individual's wages—would eventually double, leaving everyone's real purchasing power the same.

This implies that changes in interest rates driven purely by monetary factors would not lead to sustainable changes in investment or consumption decisions, as these decisions are based on real returns and real incomes. In a neutral money environment, economic agents make decisions based on real variables and relative prices, not on the absolute amount of money in circulation or nominal variables. The theory suggests that any observed impact of money on real economic activity in the short run is temporary, as prices and wages eventually adjust to restore the economy to its natural level of Gross Domestic Product and employment. The long-run adjustment means that economic resources like labor and capital are allocated based on their fundamental productivity, not on the quantity of money. If prices are "sticky" or slow to adjust, as in the case of some wages or contracts, then money may not be neutral in the short run, leading to temporary real effects, such as changes in aggregate demand or even temporary deflation.

Hypothetical Example

Consider a hypothetical economy where the money supply is fixed, and the economy is operating at its full potential. Now, imagine the central bank decides to instantaneously double the money supply by printing new currency and distributing it equally among all citizens.

According to the theory of money neutrality, here's how the scenario would unfold in the long run:

  1. Initial Impact: Initially, individuals might feel wealthier and increase their spending. This increased aggregate demand could temporarily boost sales.
  2. Price Adjustment: As everyone has more money, and the quantity of goods and services (real output) remains unchanged, businesses would respond to the increased demand by raising prices. Consumers, facing higher prices, would demand higher wages.
  3. Proportional Increase: Over time, the prices of all goods and services, as well as wages, would double. For example, a car that cost $30,000 would now cost $60,000, and a worker earning $50,000 per year would now earn $100,000.
  4. No Real Change: Despite the doubling of nominal values, the purchasing power of individuals remains the same. The ratio of prices (e.g., how many loaves of bread one car costs) does not change. The amount of goods and services produced (the real Gross Domestic Product) does not change, nor does the level of unemployment or the real interest rates in the economy. The real economy simply returns to its original state, but with a higher nominal price level.

This example illustrates the core tenet of money neutrality: money acts as a "veil," affecting only nominal values without altering the underlying real economy in the long run.

Practical Applications

While strict money neutrality is largely considered a long-run phenomenon, its practical applications influence how economists and policymakers think about monetary policy. Central banks, for example, typically focus on controlling inflation and maintaining price stability, understanding that persistent increases in the money supply without corresponding increases in real output primarily lead to higher prices. The10 Federal Reserve's dual mandate of maximum employment and stable prices reflects the understanding that while monetary policy can affect unemployment and output in the short run, its long-run influence is primarily on the price level.,,

9T8h7e theory implies that attempts to permanently stimulate real economic growth purely through printing money would be futile and only lead to runaway inflation. This perspective underpins the general consensus among central banks that fiscal policy, which involves government spending and taxation, or structural reforms, are more effective tools for influencing long-term real economic outcomes, such as productive capacity and sustainable employment. While a Central bank can influence short-term interest rates and credit conditions, its ability to permanently alter the real growth path of an economy is limited if money neutrality holds over the long term.,

#6#5 Limitations and Criticisms

Despite its theoretical elegance, money neutrality faces significant limitations and criticisms, particularly regarding its applicability in the short run. Many economists, especially those adhering to Keynesian or New Keynesian schools of thought, argue that money is not neutral in the short run due to various market imperfections.

Key criticisms include:

  • Sticky Prices and Wages: A primary critique is that prices and wages do not adjust instantaneously to changes in the money supply. Contracts, menu costs (the cost of changing prices), and psychological factors can cause "stickiness," meaning it takes time for the full adjustment to occur. During this adjustment period, changes in the money supply can have real effects on unemployment, output, and investment.
  • 4 Information Asymmetries and Money Illusion: Economic agents may not always have perfect information or may suffer from "money illusion," where they confuse nominal changes with real changes. For example, workers might perceive an increase in their nominal wages as a real gain, even if prices are rising proportionally, leading to a temporary increase in labor supply.
  • Impact on Interest Rates: Changes in the money supply can immediately affect nominal interest rates. These changes can then influence borrowing costs, investment decisions, and aggregate spending, thereby impacting real economic activity before prices fully adjust.
  • Recessions and Deflationary Spirals: In severe economic downturns, such as the Great Depression, a decrease in the money supply can lead to deflation and a contraction in real output and employment, indicating a clear short-run non-neutrality of money. In such scenarios, expansionary monetary policy may be crucial for economic recovery.
  • Hyperinflation: While seemingly supporting the idea that money affects only nominal variables, extreme cases of inflation, known as hyperinflation, demonstrate a breakdown in the functioning of money and can severely disrupt real economic activity, investment, and trade. The hyperinflation in Weimar Germany or more recently in Zimbabwe, though primarily a nominal phenomenon, had devastating real consequences for those economies.,

T3h2e concept of "superneutrality of money" is an even stricter version of the theory, positing that not only does the money supply not affect real variables, but also the rate of growth of the money supply does not affect real variables, including the real interest rate. This stricter condition is often challenged more rigorously in economic models.

##1 Money Neutrality vs. Quantity Theory of Money

Money neutrality and the Quantity theory of money are closely related concepts in Monetary economics, but they are not identical.

The Quantity Theory of Money (QTM) is a macroeconomic theory that states that the general price level of goods and services is directly proportional to the amount of money in circulation, or money supply. It is often expressed by the equation of exchange: (MV = PQ), where:

  • (M) is the total amount of money in circulation.
  • (V) is the velocity of money (the average number of times a unit of money is spent).
  • (P) is the price level.
  • (Q) is the quantity of goods and services produced (real output or real Gross Domestic Product).

For the QTM to hold in its strictest form, (V) and (Q) are assumed to be stable or determined independently of (M). If this is true, then a change in (M) must lead to a proportional change in (P).

Money Neutrality is a direct implication or consequence that arises from the Quantity Theory of Money, particularly in the long run. If the QTM holds, and changes in the money supply only affect the price level ((P)) without affecting real output ((Q)) or the velocity of money ((V)), then money is considered neutral. It means that the growth of the money supply does not influence the real side of the economy, such as employment or the production of goods.

In essence, the Quantity Theory of Money describes how changes in the money supply are transmitted to the price level, while Money Neutrality describes the consequence of this transmission on real economic variables. The QTM provides the mechanism, and money neutrality provides the outcome in the long run. The central distinction lies in the focus: QTM explains price level determination, while money neutrality explains the independence of real variables from monetary changes. In the short run, many economists argue that the velocity of money ((V)) and real output ((Q)) are not necessarily fixed, leading to the possibility of money being non-neutral.

FAQs

What is the core idea of money neutrality?

The core idea of money neutrality is that changes in the total amount of money circulating in an economy (the money supply) only affect nominal values, like prices and wages, but do not impact real economic factors, such as the total production of goods and services or the number of people employed. This concept primarily applies in the long run.

Does money neutrality apply in the short run?

Generally, no. Most economists agree that money is not strictly neutral in the short run. This is because prices and wages don't adjust instantly to changes in the money supply. Factors like contracts, consumer behavior, and information lags can cause a temporary disconnect, allowing monetary policy to have real effects on the economy, such as influencing employment or investment decisions.

What is the difference between nominal and real variables?

Nominal variables are measured in monetary units and are not adjusted for inflation (e.g., your paycheck amount, the price of a car). Real variables are adjusted for inflation and reflect the actual purchasing power or quantity of goods and services (e.g., how many goods your paycheck can buy, the actual quantity of cars produced). Money neutrality states that money only affects nominal variables.

Why is money neutrality important for central banks?

Money neutrality is important for central banks because it informs their long-term objectives. If money is neutral in the long run, then a Central bank's primary long-term role is to maintain price stability and control inflation. It suggests that attempts to use monetary policy to achieve permanent increases in real output or employment would be ineffective and only lead to higher prices.

AI Financial Advisor

Get personalized investment advice

  • AI-powered portfolio analysis
  • Smart rebalancing recommendations
  • Risk assessment & management
  • Tax-efficient strategies

Used by 30,000+ investors